Published by EH.Net (May 2022).

Janek Wasserman. *The Marginal Revolutionaries: How Austrian Economists
Fought the War of Ideas*. New Haven and London: Yale University Press,
2019. xii + 354 pp. $35 (hardcover), ISBN 978-0-300-22822-9.

Reviewed for EH.Net by Nathan P. Goodman, Department of Economics, New York
University.



Economists are social scientists, but we’re also human beings. We have
families and friends. We learn and work in professional networks. We strive
to influence the world around us. Some work in the history of economic
thought focuses on economic ideas alone, offering a narrowly doctrinal
history of our discipline. In *The Marginal Revolutionaries*, Janek
Wasserman discusses not merely the ideas of Austrian school economists, but
also their lives and relationships. The result is a rich and engaging
history of the Austrian school of economics.

Austrian economists made vital contributions to economic theory, especially
in relation to marginalism, subjectivism, opportunity cost,
entrepreneurship, and spontaneous order. This book offers a history of how
they made these contributions. Wasserman deftly weaves together both
history of economic thought and engaging description of the social,
political, and cultural context. This is especially compelling during the
earlier chapters, which discuss how Austrian economics developed in Vienna.

At its height, Vienna was an incredible center of intellectual activity.
The Austrian economists were a very important part of this intellectual
culture, but they also interacted with other intellectual circles in
Vienna. These included the logical positivists, famed psychologists such
Sigmund Freud, and influential Marxists and socialists including Rudolf
Hilferding, Otto Bauer, and Nikolai Bukharin. On the one hand, these types
of interactions illustrate just how intellectually vibrant Vienna was. They
also illustrate the crucial role that contestation and debate played in the
development of Austrian economics. Austrian economists did not merely argue
among themselves, they argued with other intellectuals who passionately
disagreed with them. These disagreements were especially sharp in their
debates with Marxists on questions such as the transformation problem,
exploitation, the feasibility of rational economic calculation under
socialism, and the relationship between capitalism and imperialism. Given
my interest in defense economics, I found the discussion of their debates
over imperialism especially fascinating.

But social science does not merely depend on arguments. The efforts of
intellectual entrepreneurs who start seminars, colloquia, academic
journals, research centers, professional organizations, and learned
societies are just as crucial. Carl Menger founded the Austrian school, but
Wasserman argues that the school formed a cohesive identity largely due to
intellectual entrepreneurship by two scholars that Menger inspired: Eugen
von Böhm-Bawerk and Friedrich von Wieser. By creating a professional
association, the Gesellschaft Österreichischer Volkswirthe (Society of
Austrian Economists, GÖV), and a corresponding journal, *Die Zeitschrift
für Volkswirtschaft, Socialpolitik und Verwaltung*, they established forums
for discussion of Austrian ideas. Throughout this period, they forged a
vibrant community of Austrian scholars, including some I had not previously
been familiar with, such as Emil Sax.

Later generations of Austrian economists continued to act as intellectual
entrepreneurs. Throughout their time in Austria, they continued to
establish discussion groups as well as more formal research centers such as
the Institute for Business Cycle Research. During World War II, most of the
Austrian economists fled from the Nazis. This emigration created an
additional need for intellectual entrepreneurship. To help their friends
and colleagues find refuge and secure employment outside of Austria,
members of the Austrian school forged new relationships and drew on
existing relationships with academics and donors. Once they had
successfully fled, they engaged in intellectual entrepreneurship to make
space for their work. The institutions they relied on in Austria had been
destroyed, and they needed to forge new paths.

This took a variety of forms. Some, such as Ludwig von Mises’s seminar in
New York and Friedrich Hayek’s role in founding the Mont Pelerin Society,
were stories I knew well. Others, such as Gottfried Haberler’s influence on
trade policy or Oskar Morgenstern’s influence within the American
military-industrial complex, were new to me. Some of these lesser known
paths illustrate the nuances of Austrian influence on global politics. The
influence of Mises, Hayek, and Murray Rothbard on libertarian and free
market political movements is well known. But Austrian influence within
more technocratic circles is less widely known, and this book helped me
better understand the diverse ways that Austrian economists influenced
policy, both in Vienna and after their emigration.

While Wasserman spends a lot of time discussing how Austrian economists
influenced politics, he also avoids a common pitfall that can occur in such
discussions. Too often, people insinuate that Austrian economics is solely
an ideological or political project. Wasserman makes sure to discuss
Austrians’ technical scientific and methodological contributions, which are
the true core of Austrian economics. While he discusses political activism
by Austrian school economists, he also discusses deliberate efforts by
Austrian economists to maintain the ideal of *wertfreiheit*, or value
freedom. While Austrian economists had political views, many of them were
clear about the difference between their prescriptive beliefs and their
social scientific descriptions of the world.

Wasserman is a great storyteller. The relationships among Austrian
economists are front and center in his account of the Austrian school. This
makes the book a fun and engaging read and helps us appreciate the social
element of scientific inquiry. If you care about Austrian economics,
history of economic thought more generally, the history of 20th century
politics, or the sociology of scientific inquiry, then I think you’ll
benefit from reading this book.



Nathan P. Goodman is a Postdoctoral Fellow in the Department of Economics
at New York University, where he is affiliated with the Program on the
Foundations of the Market Economy. His research focuses on political
economy, public choice, defense and peace economics, border militarization,
and Austrian economics.

Copyright (c) 2022 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator (
[log in to unmask]). Published by EH.Net (May 2022). All EH.Net reviews
are archived at https://www.eh.net/book-reviews.