----------------- HES POSTING -----------------
Published by EH.NET (August 2000)
Timothy L. Alborn, _Conceiving Companies: Joint-Stock Politics in Victorian
England_. London and New York: Routledge, 1998. ix + 297 pp., 5
(hardback), ISBN: 0415180791
Reviewed for EH.NET by Prabhu Guptara, International Institute for the
Management of Telecommunications, University of Fribourg, Switzerland.
<[log in to unmask]>
Since the early twentieth century, the joint-stock company and the state
have together exemplified modern bureaucratic institutions. For even
longer, companies and states have wound their way through an inconclusive
cycle of proposals to regulate, deregulate, or otherwise adjust their
boundaries. _Conceiving Companies_ suggests a new perspective on the rise
of large-scale companies by locating their origins in political and social
practice. In the process, it challenges the clear division between the
state and the market that has shaped regulatory theory and policy. In the
same way, Alborn questions the standard dichotomies of City versus
Industry, and gentleman versus philistine, as arising too much from our
seeing those times through spectacles manufactured in our own.
The book is divided into three sections, each on a different facet of
"joint-stock politics." The first section surveys the East India Company
and the Bank of England, two expressly political institutions which needed
to adjust to new tendencies in the nineteenth century to view companies as
more properly part of the market. The second locates England's early
joint-stock banks in the voluntarist and regionalist political culture of
the 1830s, then traces their departure from these origins through the end
of the century. The final section argues that Victorian railways, in
shielding themselves from state intervention, neglected their public
relations with creditors, customers and workers, and suffered economically
as a result.
Alborn's main contribution is to focus on the "political" identity of early
corporate enterprise, in contrast to earlier historians who have posited
either a heroic story of corporate growth set against a backdrop of
regulations and other outside impediments to maximum economic efficiency,
or a story about the birth of the regulatory state valiantly preserving
democracy from the worst ravages of large corporations. These approaches
lose sight of the fact that companies have never been merely
profit-maximizing machines subject to recurrent breakdowns owing to the
human error of inept state intervention, nor have they been merely selfish
agglomerates of capital in need of supervision by accountable state
authorities. Of course companies do have to make money and states are the
ultimate non-profit organization, yet companies have always had important
political accountability to shareholders, customers, workers and suppliers,
as well as environmental and other interests. So Alborn offers a new
definition of the modern company as an institution that proactively employs
a dynamic balance of political and economic means to achieve economic ends.
Recovering the modern company's political past suggests a need to
re-examine what constitutes "success" for companies: was it realistic, let
alone in their own and the public's best interest to try and depart form
their earlier conception as public institutions which both originated in
and were responsive to political concerns? In turning their back on
"politics," companies were making a calculated political decision to oppose
the emergence of a more centralized democratic state in Victorian times.
The resulting state and the resulting relationships between the state and
companies have had important economic and political consequences. To what
extent, and by what measures, was and is this "successful"?
Alborn points out that, by virtue of participating in a culture of
voluntarism and regional politics, promoters of Victorian companies arrived
at their task with a specific range of assumptions about how to raise
revenue and delegate authority. These provided them with new insights into
what economists today would recognize as more efficient methods of
organizing capital.
In doing all this, Alborn synthesizes and extends existing scholarship but,
like most other contemporary scholars of Victorian England, he
systematically ignores what was the most important ingredient of the
socio-political culture of the time - religion. The roots of religion were
of course in the "private" sphere, but the "public" sphere till at least
the end of the First World War cannot be understood without reference to
it. In that sense, Alborn is still too much a child of our times, though he
attempts systematically in other ways to raise himself beyond it.
Professor Prabhu Guptara is affiliated with the International Institute for
the Management of Telecommunications (University of Fribourg, Switzerland)
where he supervises Ph.D. research and teaches in the MBA program. He is
also Director, Executive & Organisational Development, based at the
Wolfsberg Executive Development Centre of UBS A.G. (formerly called the
Union Bank of Switzerland). His recent publications include _Top Executives
in the Global 100 Companies and Their I.T.-Competence_ (1998, ADVANCE:
Management Training Ltd. and the Wolfsberg Executive Development Centre).
Copyright (c) 2000 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator
([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2850; Fax: 513-529-3308).
Published by EH.Net (August 2000). All EH.Net reviews are archived at
http://www.eh.net/BookReview
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask]
|