SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Ross Emmett)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:20 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (208 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
 
[NOTE: The ANB puts one bio online per day. When I see ones regarding 
economists or historians of economics, I will try to post them (see their 
policy as stated at the end of the message). Others should feel free to do 
the same if they see a bio I don't! - RBE] 
 
American National Biography Online 
 
Spengler, Joseph John (19 Nov. 1902-2 Jan. 1991),  economist and 
demographer, was born near Piqua, Ohio, the son of Joseph Otto Spengler and 
Philomena Schlosser, probably farmers. In 1927 he married Dorothy Marie 
Kress; they had no children. He received the A.B. in 1926, the M.A. in 
1929, and the Ph.D. in economics in 1930, all from Ohio State University. 
His mentor at Ohio State was the well-known demographer Albert B. Wolfe. 
 
While a graduate student at Ohio State in 1927-1930, Spengler held 
instructorship appointments there. He was also a research fellow of the 
Brookings Institution in 1928. After a brief period on the faculty of the 
University of Arizona in 1930-1932 and 1933-1934, he joined the faculty of 
Duke University in Durham, North Carolina, in 1934, having spent a visiting 
year there in 1932-1933. He was a member of the Duke economics faculty for 
the remainder of his career. From 1955 on, he was a James B. Duke 
Professor. Although he retired in 1972, he continued an active scholarly 
life at Duke for another decade. 
 
Spengler's early interest in demography, as evidenced by his dissertation 
in the field, was maintained throughout his career. However, he never 
confined himself to that one field. In his first major work, France Faces 
Depopulation (1938), Spengler exhibited two professional interests in 
addition to the demographic--the history of thought and economic 
history--correlative interests that he would maintain throughout his 
career. Nevertheless, it was population problems that held center stage in 
that first major work. France Faces Depopulation argued that the recent 
history of French birth rates pointed to a significant future decline of 
the population with ominous implications for the future of France. In the 
1930s a nation's military strength was often equated with the number of men 
of military-service age in the population. This, in turn, had important 
political implications for the nation's role in world affairs. As much as 
attention has been paid to population questions in the second half of the 
twentieth century by economists, in the period in which Spengler began his 
work in demography economists paid little attention to those questions. In 
his magisterial history of economic thought, written during and immediately 
after World War II, Joseph A. Schumpeter argued that major changes in 
economic theory around 1875, which decreased emphasis on long-run 
development of an economy and increased emphasis on short-run market 
effects, especially those coming from the buyers' side, led population 
economics to, as Schumpeter put it, "wilt." 
 
What Schumpeter did not foresee was that two areas of economics--economic 
growth and economic development--would become of major importance to the 
profession in the second half of the twentieth century. In both of these 
areas population change, either directly or as reflected in labor force 
change, was a key element. In addition, the explosive growth of population 
in the world after World War II focused attention on demography and on 
related policy questions. France Faces Depopulation was republished in 
1979, forty-one years after its first publication, perhaps the ultimate 
accolade for a scholar's work. 
 
In 1940 Spengler published "Sociological Presuppositions of Economic 
Theory," an article that was a forerunner of still another lifelong 
interest--the philosophical and interdisciplinary aspects of economic 
thought. Four years after the publication of France Faces Depopulation, 
Spengler produced French Predecessors of Malthus (1942), a work that 
combined his interest in population problems with his interest in the 
history of economic ideas. There followed a brief fallow period of 
scholarly output; 1943 was the only year of his entire active career 
(1930-1980) when no scholarly publication by Spengler made an appearance. 
The reason for this was simple: he was engaged full time in 1942-1943 as 
regional price executive of Region 4 (Southeast U.S.) of the wartime Office 
of Price Administration. This experience seems to have reinforced his 
aversion to governmental bureaucracy and to bureaucrats generally. 
 
In 1948 Spengler published a striking article, "The Problem of Order in 
Economic Affairs," which had been his 1947 presidential address to the 
Southern Economic Association. It evinces Spengler's insistence on keeping 
firm contact with the real world of economic life while generalizing and 
theorizing about the social phenomenon that an economic system represents. 
In this respect, as in several others, he might be classified as an 
institutional economist but not one of a doctrinaire type. 
 
"The Problem of Order in Economic Affairs" is an example of Spengler's 
breadth of approach to large issues as well as to the erudition that 
illumined his papers written in this vein. The great challenge for the 
economic theorist is to provide an explanatory model of an economy in which 
the actions of millions of individuals result in an orderly production and 
exchange of goods and services. In the real world, each economic system, if 
it is to survive, must reconcile the autonomy of individuals with the 
necessity of their coordination in economic activity without significant 
interruption over time. Two general types predominate: the market economy 
and the state-directed economy. When Spengler wrote his presidential 
address in 1947, the contest between these two types, represented by the 
United States and the Soviet Union, was of worldwide importance. Spengler's 
article was a masterly exposition and evaluation of this contest, grounded 
in a remarkable survey of relevant economic and intellectual history. He 
headed the piece with an apt quotation from the philosopher A. N. Whitehead 
and then stated that "the problem of economic order is taking on the 
importance it had in classic Rome about the time Augustus substituted the 
principiate for the republic, and in Western Europe during the period of 
religious strife when Bodin [1530-1596] and others were searching for a 
means of unifying the community." 
 
Later, in speaking of the particularization of social science in the modern 
period, he said, "With the differentiation of social science and social 
scientists, particular hypothetical subrealms of being have fallen under 
the dominion of particular groups of social scientists who have been 
implicitly charged, somewhat after the manner of priesthoods in ancient 
Egypt, to make their respective hypothetical subrealms of being adequately 
represent the corresponding and referent real subrealms of being." Such 
seemingly casual but penetrating analogies are often found in Spengler's 
more philosophical writings. 
 
 Spengler's analytical powers were truly impressive, at times approaching prescience.
Speaking forty years before the Soviet Union began to crumble, he said in "Problem of
Order" that "a centrally planned economy . . . almost certainly will neither maximize the
rate of growth of per capita income nor bring about the particular kind of coordination
most men want. For the entrepreneurial state lacks and probably will continue to lack the
know-how, the moral integrity, the inventiveness, the capacity to give incentive, and the
flexibility of economic behavior requisite in a dynamic world."
 
 These three broad themes--demography, the history of economics, and the relationship of
economics to other disciplines (especially philosophy and sociology)--were pursued by
Spengler throughout his long professional career. In a period in which the discipline of
economics became increasingly specialized and more and more isolated from other related
areas of study, Spengler refused to narrow his interests. One important lesson of his
career is
that diverse but wisely chosen areas of study can reinforce one another. 
Thus he demonstrated that all scholarly productivity gains need not require 
increasing scholarly specialization. 
 
Spengler's career was not a cloistered one. He was active in various 
professional organizations, a number of which honored him with an office or 
other distinction. He served as president not only of the Southern Economic 
Association (1947) but of the Population Association of America (1957), the 
American Economic Association (1965), and the Atlantic Economic Association 
(1976-1977) as well. His relationship with the History of Economics Society 
was a particularly close one; he was a founding member and a moving spirit 
in its birth in 1968. Later he served as its president and was honored as 
its distinguished fellow. He was also a key figure in the inauguration in 
1968 of the History of Political Economy journal, published at Duke. These 
two initiatives revivified an important field of economics. Their 
continuing viability is testimony to the foresight of Spengler and a few 
colleagues at Duke. 
 
A particularly fitting honor was Spengler's election in 1954 to the 
American Philosophical Society because the breadth of his intellectual 
interests exemplified the aims of that organization. He was also a 
recipient of the society's John F. Lewis Award. In very different arenas, 
he was a fellow of both the American Statistical Association, a recognition 
of his contributions to 
the mathematics of population change, and the American Association of Arts 
and Sciences. Finally, his individualistic political stance was reflected 
in his membership in the Mt. Pellerin Society, a conservative, libertarian 
group. He died in Durham. 
 
 In an assessment of Spengler's contribution for the American Philosophical Society, Allen
Kelley, Spengler's colleague and close associate in his demographic work, said, "Professor
Spengler's lifetime research program on the nexus of economics and demography represents
his most important seminal contribution to the advancement of knowledge" (Kelley, p. 143).
Spengler began his work in demography and economics when population questions were almost
excluded from mainstream economics. More than anyone else of his generation of scholars,
Spengler changed that situation. Indeed, at first he was almost alone in the endeavor, but
Spengler never sought to march to someone else's drum. He possessed a kind of intellectual
courage and independence rare in scholarly circles.
 
 
Bibliography 
 
For additional information on Spengler, including a bibliography of his 
demographic and other publications for the period 1929-1971, see Robert S. 
Smith et al., eds., Population Economics: Selected Essays of Joseph J. 
Spengler (1972), pp. 515-28. His later articles are indexed in American 
Economic Association, Index of Economic Articles, annual volumes for 
1972-1980 and 1982-1984. Two of Spengler's later works are Indian Economic 
Thought: Preface to 
Its History (1971) and Origins of Economic Thought and Justice (1980). 
Spengler's own estimate, made late in life, was that he had published more 
than 250 articles. An assessment of his contributions to the field of 
demography is Allen C. Kelley, Proceedings of the American Philosophical 
Society 136 (1992): 142-47; a photograph accompanies this article. A 
similar assessment of Spengler's contributions to the history of economics 
is in Irving Sobel, "Joseph J. Spengler: The Institutionalist Approach to 
the History of Economics," in The Craft of the Historian of Economic 
Thought, ed. Warren J. Samuels (1983). An evaluation by a former student is 
that of Leonard Silk in the New York Times, 4 Jan. 1991. An obituary is in 
the New York Times, 3 Jan. 1991. 
 
Royall Brandis 
 
--------------------- 
Suggested citation: 
 Royall Brandis. "Spengler, Joseph John"; 
http://www.anb.org/articles/14/14-01077.html  
American National Biography Online April 2001 
 
Copyright Notice 
Permission is granted to make and distribute verbatim copies of the 
American National Biography of the Day and Sample Biographies provided that 
the following statement is preserved on all copies: 
 
     From American National Biography, published by Oxford University 
     Press, Inc., copyright 2000 American Council of Learned Societies. 
     Further information is available at http://www.anb.org. 
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2