SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Ross Emmett)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:19:00 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (143 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
 
Published by EH.NET (March 2001) 
 
Michael Perelman, _The Invention of Capitalism: Classical Political  
Economy and the Secret History of Primitive Accumulation_. Durham,  
NC: Duke University Press, 2000. 412 pp. 2,95 (paper), ISBN:  
0-8223-2491-1; 4.95 (cloth), ISBN: 0-8223-2454-7. 
 
Reviewed for EH.NET by Gregory Clark, Department of Economics,  
University of California-Davis. <[log in to unmask]> 
 
 
One of our popular diversions here in California is "channeling" the  
thoughts of those who have passed on to the spirit world. Michael  
Perelman has seemingly by these methods made contact with Karl Marx  
himself. For his book is a lively polemic directed at the Classical  
political economists, full of allegations of double dealing and bad  
faith, that the master himself would have been proud to deliver. Marx  
lives. He lives in Chico, California. 
 
Perelman interprets Classical political economy as a political  
program in search of an intellectual justification. Classical  
economists wanted to promote the interests of the new capitalist  
class. To this end the Classical system celebrated the virtues of the  
free market. But free markets were of no use if the capitalist class  
could not recruit the wage slaves they needed for their factories. So  
Classical economists simultaneously promoted intervention in markets  
to strip the peasantry and handicraft workers of the vestiges of  
their independence and reduce them to the wage labor. They advocated  
in Marx's terms (or at least in the terms of Marx's English  
translators) "primitive accumulation" as necessary to make a market  
economy. But they did not advocate this openly: thus the "secret  
history of primitive accumulation." Free competition was optimal,  
unless it produced an independent peasantry unwilling to submit to  
wage labor. "While energetically promoting their laissez-faire  
ideology, they championed time and again policies that flew in the  
face of their laissez-faire principles" (pp. 2-3). 
 
Exhibit A in Perelman's indictment of the Classical mob is the case  
of the Game Laws. The Game Laws banned the landless and small owners  
in the countryside from taking game animals. Thus in England by the  
laws of 1670 to take game even on your own land a person had to meet  
a very substantial property qualification. In both England and  
Scotland these laws became more severe as the eighteenth century  
progressed, and more people were convicted under the laws. Why, asks  
Perelman, did the new capitalist class and their PR agents, the  
Political Economists, support these feudal restrictions in favor of  
the country squires? They did so because it took away the sources of  
support that kept the poor in the countryside from the factory door.  
They did so because a hunting peasant was an idle peasant and an  
insolent peasant, not a docile and dependable worker. 
 
That is the Perelman claim. What is his evidence? The main evidence  
that Classical political economy promoted the game laws to dispossess  
the peasantry is their almost complete silence on the subject! Adam  
Smith, "that great master of capitalist apologetics" (p. 49), was,  
writes Perelman, the only Classical Economist to ever mention the  
Game Laws. Smith, however, condemned the game laws as a feudal relic,  
noting that "The reason they give is that the prohibition is made to  
prevent the lower sort of people from spending their time on such  
unprofitable employment; but the real reason is that they delight in  
hunting" (p. 50). In light of this Perelman concludes this discussion  
by noting generously that "Although Smith refuses to acknowledge any  
association between the Game Laws and the interests of capital, he  
deserves some credit for broaching the subject, since all other  
political economists failed to make any mention whatsoever" (p. 51). 
 
Since Classical writers cunningly concealed their support and  
promotion of the Game Laws by not discussing them, or pretending to  
be opposed to them, their guilt is established by the silence of  
their friends in Parliament on the issue. "When Parliament debated  
the Game Laws again in 1830, not one prominent spokesperson for  
political economy called for their abolition" (p. 54). The  
alternative hypothesis, that Classical economists really thought the  
Game Laws were a feudal relic too minor to bother with, is not  
explored. 
 
Exhibit B in the indictment of the Classical mob is their treatment of household "self
provisioning" or as Perelman also refers to it
"the social division of labor." Here again we know of their bad faith  
in this matter in the contrast between their obvious desire to  
destroy self-provisioning and force all workers into the market and  
their public silence on the issue. Thus "Smith, insofar as he  
addresses the subject, treated the social division of labor as the  
result of voluntary choices on the part of free people" (p. 90). On  
the other hand any random statement by anyone criticizing sloth or  
indiscipline by independent producers is sign of a plan to  
eliminating independence and create a proletariat. 
 
It is true that Classical economists often wrote about the indolence  
of the poor and of smallholders. But was this casual moralizing just  
a relic of earlier modes of discourse, on the way to a more  
systematic way of thinking about the economy? Here I read their  
general silence on the issue very differently. It is the silence that  
shows that concern with forcing the poor to labor for wages was a  
peripheral element of their system. Perelman, has to transform this  
casual silence into a much more sinister conspiracy to conceal. The  
book makes little progress in that direction. Indeed the bold links  
drawn on the most tenuous of evidence are one thing that  
distinguishes the Chico Marx from the original. Those connections are  
so bold that this book might better be placed on the shelf with the  
"grassy knoll" and "Roswell" genres. 
 
As a historian who has written on England in the Industrial  
Revolution period I have a more innocent interpretation of the  
Classical conspiracy of silence on the alleged expropriation of the  
peasantry. This is that the process whereby independent peasants and  
artisans became wage laborers was already largely complete in England  
by the time the Classical economists arrived on the scene in the  
eighteenth century. Their silence on the issue is a silence of true  
indifference. They had no need to conspire in the expropriation of  
the means of subsistence by capitalists, because a free labor market  
was in place. The issue of common rights, access to land, and  
self-provisioning had been settled in favor of wage labor by 1700 in  
all but the rural fastnesses of the Scottish highlands. Even before  
the formal Parliamentary enclosure movement of 1750 and later common  
rights had mainly become private tradable rights of access unlikely  
to be owned by the poorest workers. Truly common areas with free  
access were limited and of little value (see Leigh Shaw-Taylor, "Did  
Agricultural Laborers Have Common Rights?" forthcoming, _Journal of  
Economic History_, and "Labourers, Cows, Common Rights and  
Parliamentary Enclosure: The Evidence of Contemporary Comment, c.  
1760-1810" forthcoming, _Past and Present_). 
 
Perelman, like Marx, suffers from a wildly romantic vision of a  
pre-industrial England of laughter and leisure that accords little  
with reality. Marx had the excuse that he was writing at a time when  
little was known about that past. 
 
 
Gregory Clark is Professor of Economics at the University of California, Davis. 
 
Copyright (c) 2001 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be  
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to  
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the  
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2850;  
Fax: 513-529-3308). Published by EH.Net (March 2001). All EH.Net  
reviews are archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview  
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2