SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Ross Emmett)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:23 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (214 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
 
Published by EH.NET (August 2002) 
 
John Cornwall and Wendy Cornwall, _Capitalist Development in the Twentieth 
Century: An Evolutionary-Keynesian Approach_. Cambridge and New York: 
Cambridge University Press, 2001. xv + 286 pp. $60 (hardback), ISBN: 
0-521-34149-3. 
 
Reviewed for EH.Net by Richard Vedder, Department of Economics and College 
of Business, Ohio University. <[log in to unmask]> 
 
 
As David Colander accurately states in his forward to _Capitalist 
Development in the Twentieth Century_, John and Wendy Cornwall "are true, 
unrepentant Keynesians." In this _tour de horizon_ of modern macroeconomic 
history, aggregate demand is the leading actor -- cycles in economic 
performance are determined by the robustness of aggregate demand. The 
Cornwalls more or less believe in the reverse of Say's Law: Demand creates 
its own Supply. 
 
The authors believe that the best single indicator of an economy's 
macroeconomic performance is the rate of unemployment. Unemployment 
was relatively low or "full" in many Westernized nations in the 1920s, and 
especially in the "golden age" of the 1950s and 1960s. The reason, they 
believe, is that aggregate demand was growing by healthy amounts in those 
eras. By contrast, the period since 1973 has been one of sluggish economic 
performance, explainable in large part by institutional (often 
government-imposed) restraints in the growth in aggregate demand. The slow 
growth in aggregate demand, the authors opine, has led to reduced savings, 
investment, and productivity growth. Of particular importance, nations 
where labor, business and government reached "social bargains" (incomes 
policies) were able to stimulate aggregate demand through government 
policy, but most of these social bargains fell by the wayside after 1973. 
 
While my overall impression of the book is not favorble, it nonetheless has 
several strengths. Let me mention four. First, it is reasonably well 
written, using enough symbols, jargon and econometrics to keep professional 
economists satisfied, yet at the same time it is clear enough for the 
intelligent layperson to understand the rudiments of the main points. In an 
era and profession where writing incomprehensibly is considered to be a 
sign of virtue and erudition, this is no small accomplishment. To be sure, 
the discussion of such things as "hysteretic processes with exogenous 
origins" (p.102) is filled with typical academic pretentious jargon that 
would put the most diehard Keynesian to sleep, but on the whole this book 
is above average in clarity for economist-written works. 
 
Second, the book makes an important point, that many economic model 
builders ignore, specifically that institutional arrangements and the 
structure of the economy matter, and often matter a great deal. Moreover, 
as the Cornwalls observe, institutional arrangements change over time with 
economic changes, and this can impact economic performance. 
 
Third, while the authors are truly militant Keynesians, they realize that a 
1950-style old Keynesian story simply will not cut it in today's world. In 
particular, they eschew Keynes's emphasis on the short run, and try to 
evaluate the impact that aggregate demand has on intermediate to longer run 
economic growth. With the decline in the importance of the business cycle, 
this is a necessary adjustment. The Cornwalls also reject or downplay much 
of the New Keynesian emphasis on microanalysis of wage and price rigidities 
(e.g., efficiency wages, menu costs, and so forth). Borrowing some from 
ideas of the New Institutional Economics, the Cornwalls believe that 
evolutionary changes in institutions and economic structure have an 
important role to play in explaining changing economic performance. 
 
Lastly, as EH.NET readers will applaud, the Cornwalls appreciate the 
importance of history, ad its usefulness in assessing economic phenomena. 
While not economic historians, they have written what is a somewhat less 
than comprehensive but still interesting macroeconomic history of the 
twentieth century within the context of trying to explain what makes the 
macroeconomic world work. 
 
Yet, despite all of these virtues, this is in my judgment a badly flawed 
book for a simple reason: I think the authors are just plain wrong in their 
assessments. Moreover, they are not merely sporadically wrong, but 
persistently and unrelentingly mistaken. To borrow a favorite Cornwallian 
term, this book suffers a bad case of misguided intellectual hysteresis. To 
be fair, I am not a Keynesian (although I started out as one), so a priori 
one would not expect a particularly positive assessment of this work from 
me. But I suspect that more neutral observers on the 
Keynesian/non-Keynesian continuum would find many of the same objections. 
 
Before enumerating some problems with the Cornwalls' analysis, I would make 
an obvious point that the issue of whether economic progress is supply or 
demand-induced is not a new one. For example, many trees have been 
destroyed making books on the question of whether the Industrial Revolution 
is best explained by emphasizing supply or demand. In an era where demand 
is increasingly taken for granted, the Cornwalls' book does make us at 
least consider the possibility that the new (post-Keynes) conventional 
wisdom might be wrong. 
 
I would also note that in some respects Cornwall and Cornwall show 
deference to an early, classical tradition that in some ways is the 
antithesis of Keynesian economics as practiced in the original by Keynes 
himself. For example, the authors stress the importance of capital 
formation in long-term growth, a view far more akin to Adam Smith than to 
Keynes. Original Keynesian analysis vilified savings, the funding source 
for capital formation, yet Cornwall and Cornwall believe that investment is 
critical to the dnamic process of long-run economic transformation. There 
is a bit of Adam Smith, and also a lot of Joseph Schumpeter, in the 
Cornwall and Cornwall interpretation of history. 
 
Turning to the objections, it is argued that there are swings in economic 
performance explainable by changes in the robustness of aggregate demand 
influenced by institutional changes. In particular, the 1950s and 1960s 
were the "golden age" of modern economies, and the era since 1973 has been 
something of a disaster because of declining growth in aggregate demand. 
 
Virtually the sole criterion used to evaluate economic performance is the 
unemployment rate. Unemployment is higher in the last three decades, so 
economic performance has worsened. I would suggest this is a highly 
questionable basic premise as it pertains to the U.S., although it is 
certainly more defensible for Europe. While average unemployment rates in 
the 1980s and 1990s were higher than in the 1950s and 1960s in the U.S., by 
most other measures the economy in the latter period either approximately 
equaled or surpassed the earlier record. Real per capita GDP grew 57 
percent from 1950 to 1970 - and 55 percent from 1980 to 2000 - hardly an 
important distinction. Real household wealth rose faster in the latter 
period, and real per capita consumption rose by almost the same amount in 
both periods. Job creation was actually _greater_ in the latter period -- 
the number of new jobs per 100 incremental population over 16 was 64 in the 
1950-70 period, compared with 81 in the 1980-2000 era. 
 
The authors assert that increased unemployment was involuntary in nature, 
citing the rising duration of unemployment as evidence. I would argue that 
most the rise in unemployment, especially in Europe, reflected onerous new 
labor regulations and the impact that increasingly generous welfare state 
benefits had on the desire to work. Reservation wages rose sharply as the 
alternative to work -- long-lived generous welfare benefits -- bcame a 
viable option. Why is the duration of unemployment more than twice as high 
in Germany as in the U.S.? Germans can collect generous unemployment 
benefits for three to four times as long as Americans without any adverse 
consequences. These unemployed are hardly "involuntarily" out of work. A 
secondary factor in the unemployment rise in the 1970s and 1980s was 
demographic: an increase in the proportion of workers in young age cohorts 
that are typically more unemployment-prone. 
 
The Cornwalls _assert_ that governmental macro fiscal and monetary policies 
can reduce unemployment through heightened aggregate demand. It is argued 
that political constraints limited the use of demand stimulus after 1973. 
The evidence shows otherwise. In the U.S. the federal government ran far 
greater fiscal deficits on average in the two decades after 1973 than in 
the two decades before. For example, in the midst of the "golden age" of 
the 1960s, the federal deficit was less than one percent of GDP in eight of 
ten years, while the smallest deficit in the 1980s was nearly three times 
that amount. Monetary growth on average was greater in the latter era as 
well (the median annual growth rate of M1 in the 1960s was 3.5 percent; in 
the 1980s, it was 7.0 percent). The same pattern generally is true in 
Europe. The Cornwalls simply refuse to admit the problem may have been the 
impotency of macro stimulus, and they claim fiscal/monetary constraint in 
the latter period prevented full employment, despite the evidence that such 
constraint was simply not present. 
 
The discussion of the Great Depression is also wanting. Other than the 
Friedman-Schwartz monetary explanation, there is no mention of other 
non-Keynesian explanations of the Depression, including ones stressing 
international monetary disturbances (e.g., Barry Eichengreen), Austrian 
business cycles, or the Hoover high wage policy. The Keynesian argument 
explaining the Depression was made better, in this author's judgmnt, by 
earlier writers such as E. Cary Brown. 
 
Moreover, there is not a scintilla of hard evidence relating to the "social 
bargains" (incomes policy) allegedly common in the 1950s and 1960s compared 
with later years. There is no description of how these policies worked in 
specific countries, for example. We are supposed to take on blind faith the 
repeated assertion that income policies worked in producing the golden age 
of the 1950s and 1960s, but broke down somehow after 1973. Somehow a single 
regression equation (p. 91) with no social bargain variables is construed 
to support the Cornwalls' incredibly weak argument. 
 
The book is full of absolutely wild assertions. A few samples: "The view 
that an increase in aggregate demand will not reduce involuntary 
unemployment because it is unable to reduce the real wage contains the 
implicit assumption that the real wage is determined in the labor market. 
This assumption has been shown to be unrealistic..." (p. 46) A single 
unpublished paper from 1990 is used to back up this assertion. Better yet, 
"Over two decades of neoliberalism have revealed its similarities to the 
laissez-faire regimes of earlier times -- prosperity for the few and 
insecurity for many" (p. 268). To argue that in, say, the 1990s, few had 
prosperity but many were economically insecure in the U.S. or Europe is 
simply fiction. Speaking of the era after the golden age, the authors claim 
that "the role of government in domestic and international economic affairs 
has been greatly reduced, social bargains no longer dominate labor market 
outcomes and price stability has become an overriding economic goal" (p. 
242). It is a fact that government spending as a percent of GDP has risen, 
not fallen, in nearly every major western industrialized country in the era 
since the so-called golden age, and regulatory activity has increased as 
well. To say that government's role has been "greatly reduced" simply 
defies the factual evidence. 
 
The posibility that rising unemployment and sluggish growth in Europe 
reflects the debilitating effects of high taxation, regulatory rigidities, 
and the disincentive effects of the welfare state is virtually ignored. 
There are a variety of plausible explanations for economic changes that 
have occurred in the past several decades, but the Cornwalls have not 
presented them. Save your money: don't buy this book. 
 
 
Richard Vedder is co-author of _Out of Work: Unemployment and Government in 
Twentieth-Century America_ (New York: New York University Press, 1997). 
 
Copyright (c) 2002 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied 
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and 
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator 
([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2850; Fax: 513-529-3308). 
Published by EH.Net (August 2002). All EH.Net reviews are archived at 
http://www.eh.net/BookReview 
 
 
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2