----------------- HES POSTING -----------------
Published by EH.NET (December 2003)
Eric Kerridge, _Usury, Interest and the Reformation_. Aldershot, UK:
Ashgate, 2002. xv + 191 pp. $79.95 (cloth), ISBN: 0-7546-0688-0.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Norman Jones, Department of History, Utah State
University.
Eric Kerridge has been in the first rank of economic historians of early
modern England since his _The Agricultural Revolution_ appeared in 1967,
followed shortly by his _Agrarian Problems in the Sixteenth Century and
After_ (1969), and several other books, including his important _Trade and
Banking in Early Modern England_ (1983). Given his expertise in financial
instruments and the ways in which trade and agriculture were actually
carried out, this book holds out the promise of a nuts-and-bolts approach
to usury and interest. Surprisingly, that is not what it delivers. Its 76
pages of text present an overview of the intellectual history of the debate
over usury in Germany and England in the sixteenth and seventeenth
centuries. The book's thesis is summarized in its ultimate paragraph: "Yet
even the gravest matters of scholarship are as nothing compared to the
transcendental importance of acquitting Christians of the charge of having
countenanced usury and usurers" (p. 76).
The short text is accompanied by 38 documents, in their original languages
as well as in translation, that provide proof texts for his argument. They
are referenced in the body of the text, so that the reader can see at
length the nature of the arguments under discussion. This feature usefully
assembles bits of Aquinas, Bernardine of Siena, Calvin, Bullinger, Luther,
Melanchthon, Zwingli, Wycliffe, Jewel, and a few others across a span of
time from the thirteenth to the seventeenth century.
Kerridge contends that no historian of usury has understood what it was in
law and theology, so he carefully lays out the legal definition of usury,
as opposed to legal interest charges as permitted in the extrinsic titles
of the canon law. As he rightly insists, "interest," which always involved
risk, was legal, while "usury," a corrupt contract for certain gain on the
sum lent, was never legal. In particular, Kerridge berates R.H. Tawney for
his misunderstanding of Luther's thought on usury as represented in his
_Religion and the Rise of Capitalism_ (a misunderstanding that is not in
evidence in Tawney's edition of Thomas Wilson's _A Discourse on Usury_).
Although Tawney bears the brunt of his critique, he dismisses all the main
works on usury with a footnote. It seems that he believes that no one has
understood this technical difference between usury and interest.
It is a charge that comes as something of a surprise, but it arises,
apparently, from a very different agenda than that of other students of
usury. Tawney and Max Weber, Benjamin Nelson and John Noonan, and I, were
interested in the interplay between religious ideology and the emergence of
a particular kind of capitalism in the early modern period. We were
concerned with how theologies were interpreted, how they were transmuted
into law, how the individual conscience and the legal contract conformed to
or fudged the official line on usury. It was always illegal, but what it
was, in the popular mind, evolved. Although Kerridge is well aware of this
evolution, he is concerned to correct the errors of both scholars and
contemporary publics.
Kerridge can say, rightly, that some Protestant theologians in Germany,
Switzerland and England did not tolerate usury. But by concentrating on a
few well-known theologians, he controls the outcome of his argument.
Missing are the other voices in the debate. Anyone who has read Thomas
Wilson's _Dialogue_ is aware that there were several conflicting
interpretations of when and how the sin of usury occurred, and who was
expected to regulate it. We are not informed, for instance, of the
arguments of Johannes Eck, or Charles du Moulin, or Conrad Summenhart, or
Louis Molina, or Navarrus over _census, lucrum cessans_, and the _mons
pietatis_ that opened Christian ways around more conservative arguments. In
particular, his definition of the Reformation as a purely Protestant affair
removes the discussion of usury from the larger European context and allows
him to ignore the fruitful thinking of the Spanish Jesuits on the subject.
In that sense, Max Weber's _Protestantism and the Spirit of Capitalism_
lives on in Kerridge's conception of the problem.
This little book provides a concise and very scholarly introduction to the
arguments about usury, its definition in canon law and English law, and how
interest was defined as different. It is immensely learned, too, with
half-page footnotes and all quotes in both the original languages and in
translation. The reader, however, is dropped in at the deep end of
definition, and he or she must read with care in order to keep the
technical arguments straight. But does it advance our understanding of the
possible links between Protestantism and evolving attitudes toward secured
loans at interest? Not really. He does prove that some Protestant
theologians insisted that usury remained a sin, and that many people
confused usury and interest, but he is not interested in pushing his
argument beyond this. To demonstrate that a theologian of the early
sixteenth century and one of the late seventeenth agreed with one of the
thirteenth ignores the very different economic realities in which their
thinking took place.
In the end, one is left wishing that Kerridge had opened up the scope a bit
more and used his great learning to engage the debate over evolving credit
practices and their relation to ideas about money, credit, and sin in Early
Modern England.
Norman Jones is the author of several books including _God and the
Moneylenders: Usury and Law in Early Modern England_ (1989), and _The
English Reformation: Religion and Cultural Adaptation_ (2002).
Copyright (c) 2003 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator
([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2851). Published by EH.Net
(December 2003). All EH.Net reviews are archived at
http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask]
|