Subject: | |
From: | |
Date: | Thu Aug 7 16:53:01 2008 |
Content-Type: | text/plain |
Parts/Attachments: |
|
|
Perhaps one significant reason why few historians
of economics have studied its contemporary forms
is the difficulty of the task. If one wants to
call oneself a historian of economics, one can do
so more easily by studying pre-WWII economics. As
history is about the past, the study of long-dead
economists can more readily be identified with
history than that of living economists. But
historians would not be duped. History is not
just about the past: it is about its
construction. And this explains much of the
inattention to contemporary economics. Whereas
historians of long-dead economists can take
advantage of the confusion between the
chronological past and the constructed past,
historians of recent economics cannot: they need
to build this past that some still consider their
present. If one studies contemporary economics
and claims it to be history, one needs to show
that one is constructing a past in a way that
marks it out as history not as a contribution to
contemporary economics - that it is not, for
example, a survey article.
Perhaps Roy Weintraub's question can be
reformulated in a slightly different way: Is it
so surprising that people who call themselves
historians of economics but were not trained as
historians show little interest in recent
economics when historians themselves can have
trouble placing the writing historically about
the present time? A few years ago, the Ecole
normale sup?rieure de Cachan hosted an Institut
d'histoire du temps pr?sent. There most
historians were studying WWII. Even they were not
studying more recent history than that.
Philippe Fontaine
|
|
|