SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Ross Emmett)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:19:11 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (146 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
Published by EH.NET (November 2003) 
 
Steven Kates, editor, _Two Hundred Years of Say's Law: Essays on Economic Theory's Most
Controversial Principle _. Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar, 2003. x + 221 pp. $85 (hardcover),
ISBN: 1-84064-866-X.
 
Reviewed for EH.NET by Ingrid H. Rima, Department of Economics, Temple University. 
 
The year 2003 marks the two hundredth year anniversary of the generalization that has come
to be known as Say's Law. As with any other anniversary that has had a significant impact
on the development of economics -- specifically macroeconomics -- this anniversary is
deserving of commemoration. Steven Kates' undertakes to do this in a volume whose subtitle
is "Essays on Economic Theory's Most Controversial Principle."
 
Some historical background is useful for putting the eleven essays that comprise this
collection into perspective. The editor's thirty-two page introduction traces the origins
of J. B. Say's concept of demand deficiency in response to a pamphlet by William Spence
written during the Napoleonic Wars between France and England arguing that the loss of
trade did no great harm because agriculture was the chief source of the economy's value
added. This resurgence of Physiocratic doctrine in England about the centrality of
landowner expenditure in maintaining the economy's prosperity, provoked a response by
James Mill in _Commerce Defended_. This essay substantially denied, on the basis of an
earlier argument by J. B. Say against the French Physiocrats that a deficiency of
aggregate demand is an impossibility. Subsequently known as the "law of markets," the Say-
Mill generalization maintained that the production of output simultaneously generates
aggregate purchasing power of sufficient value to clear markets of the entire output,
which renders the insufficiency of purchasing power an impossibility. It is this
perspective that essentially became the pre-Keynesian theory of recession that maintained,
quite simply, that excess supplies of _some_ goods could arise because some outputs have
been produced in inappropriate proportions, but that _gluts_ in the sense of insufficient
demand for output as a whole are an impossibility. The essence of Keynes's argument in the
_General Theory_ (1936) and the 1937 _Economic Journal_ article that followed asserted the
fallacy of Say's Law given the absence in received economic theory of "a theory of supply
and demand for output as a whole."
 
Some years afterward a 1942 paper by Oskar Lange entitled "Say's Law: A Restatement and
Criticism" shifted the ground of the argument from the functioning of commodity markets to
that of the money market. His argument was that Say's Law holds because, implicitly,
additional cash is never wanted, so that the demand for goods is _necessarily_ the
equivalent of the supply of goods with the result that unemployment cannot occur. This
logic (also that of Alfred Marshall) led to the perspective that the theory of monetary
markets must begin with a consideration of Say's Law. William Baumol entered into the
argument noting that, while fluctuations in aggregate demand may be the source of
recessions and depression, the appearance of demand deficiency may well be a _symptom_
rather than a cause of recession. His paper "Say's Law and More Recent Macro Literature:
Some Afterthoughts" is an appropriate prelude to the eleven essays that follow, including
his own ("Retrospectives: Say's Law") republished from the _Journal of Economic
Perspectives_ (1999). The essays in the volume thus proceed from what the editor and the
volume's contributors consider Baumol's perceptive insights into "the next stage of the
debate" (p. 6) about Say's Law. He is particularly concerned to emphasize that Keynes was,
in fact, using the generalization that has become known as "Say's Identity" as a
"strawman" to criticize "the classics," notwithstanding the concern that Malthus, Ricardo
and Say expressed about unemployment and depression.
 
Evelyn L. Forget sets the stage for the essays that follow with her intellectual biography
of J. B. Say as a political economist and entrepreneur. He engaged in the real world of
business decision making that was then, as today, "complete with less than optimal
bureaucracies, less than omniscient entrepreneurs, and a good deal less than perfect
foresight" (p.51). For Forget, Say's own use of the law of markets, to which the role of
the entrepreneur was central, is found to have been fundamentally different from the
automatic adjustment mechanism that Keynes rejected and casually labeled "classical" in
_The General Theory_.
 
Given the disappearance of Say's Law from contemporary discourse since _The General
Theory_, the essays that follow undertake to evaluate, whether the profession has also
become deprived of the valuable insights about the phenomenon of overproduction that were
historically the subject matter of business cycle theory. Steven Kates's "Economic
Management and the Keynesian Revolution" addresses the question from the policy
perspective of Keynes's "solution" of offsetting aggregate demand deficiencies with
increased public spending. Because "savings do not lie fallow but are channeled into
investment," Kates considers the policy to not be "economically sound." The Keynesian case
is thus threadbare, and "other explanations for recession and involuntary unemployment are
required" (p.79). In short, Kates' argument is that recessions are not caused by a failure
of demand. This argument is the segue into papers by Steven Horowitz and Mark Skousen,
which pursue "the case in favor of a modern rehabilitation of Say's Law" from the
perspective of F. A. Hayek and other supply side economists. Skousen's paper is
particularly interesting in its argument that, empirically, business investment is a more
reliable predictor of the business cycle than the consumption data suggested by Keynes's
focus on the consumption expenditures of households. For Skousen these findings suggest
the relevance of giving greater credence to supply side forces -- specifically the role of
entrepreneurs -- as the source of dynamic change in an economy. The preceding arguments
against Keynes-type demand management policies echo James Akiakpor in "Say's Law: Keynes's
Success with Its Misrepresentation." Together with Timothy Davis's analogous paper "The
Historical Context of the General Glut Controversy," he offers a review of the events
surrounding the so-called "glut controversy" that engaged Ricardo, Malthus and J. B. Say
during the nineteenth century.
 
The remaining four papers examine what the editor's introduction identifies as "the case
for Say's Law"; these reaffirm not only Keynes's principle of aggregate demand, but also
more contemporary theoretical developments. The first among these is Michael George's
paper "Savings, Hoarding and Say's Law," which focuses on the role of hoarding and the
relationship between variations in the interest rate and speculation explored by Alfred
Marshall and Frederick Lavington. This historical inquiry is interesting in its own right,
yet it is hardly reflective of the contemporary post-Keynesian perspective of "money as an
asset." Modern monetary production economies are fundamentally different from those
trading use values, e.g., iron for corn, which evolved historically once the era of
economic self-sufficiency passed. Monetary production economies are not concerned with the
production of use values, but are concerned with the production of commodities for sale in
order to generate profit. The role of money in a C - M - C' economy is its immediate use
for the purchase of other products, whereas in an M - C - M+ economy (which is
characteristic of capitalism) money is to facilitate the accumulation of money (i.e.,
wealth) for its own sake.
 
As is elaborated by Steve Keen in the concluding paper of the volume, it is Karl Marx who
described the "circuits" of capitalism in which he contrasts the process of exchanging use
values for money in order to command other use values vs. exchanging money to purchase the
use value of labor power in order to generate surplus value. Thus, money is more than a
"lubricant" for barter (as perceived by Say); it is the form in which wealth is
accumulated. There is no guarantee that exchanges undertaken within the M - C - M+ circuit
can achieve either a sectoral or aggregate balance in which expectations are realized so
that the debts undertaken to finance production processes do (given the uncertainty which
characterizes the system), in fact, finance the sale of output at a profit.
 
Although the origin of Kates' collection of essays is attributed to a (student) query
whether "supply creates its own demand" or the other way around, Keynes's raison d'etre
for asking the question is the inherent instability and proneness of capitalism to
unemployment and unused capacity. Only Bruce Littleboy's "Say's Law" paper fully
appreciates the critical link between Keynes's representation of Say's Law and the
"classics," and his central concern about the phenomenon of large scale job losses. While
involuntary unemployment is noted in Kates's editorial introduction (p.10), the seeming
disinterest of other contributors to examine it further within the framework of the supply
side analysis he favors, and with which it is not inherently incompatible, is somewhat
surprising. It also compromises his argument that classical economics has greater
analytical and policy relevance that the aggregate demand analysis to which _The General
Theory_ gave rise. The classicals, as Baumol clearly appreciates, were concerned about
unemployment and depression. None the less, Kates's collection of papers to revisit
classical economics and Say's Law offers contemporary economists (few of whom nowadays
have had the benefit of formal training in the history of economics) at least some
appreciation of the profound insights that the "old classicals" offer, in particular, in
comparison to the body of ideas that are now termed "new classical."
 
Ingrid Rima's publications include _Development of Economic Analysis_, Routledge (sixth
edition), 2000.
 
Copyright (c) 2003 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied for non-profit
educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and the list. For other
permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-
529-2851; Fax: 513-529-3308). Published by EH.Net (November 2003). All EH.Net reviews are
archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview
 
 
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2