SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Ross Emmett)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:35 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (389 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
Published by EH.NET (January 2003) 
 
Walter Scheidel and Sitta von Reden, editors, _The Ancient Economy_. 
Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 2002. xxi + 282 pp. £16.99 
(paperback), ISBN: : 0-7486-1321-8; £45 (hardback), ISBN: 0-7486-1322-6. 
 
Reviewed for EH.NET by Morris Silver, Professor Emeritus, Department of 
Economics, City College of the City University of New York. 
 
 
In 1973, the classical scholar Moses Finley (1973, 1985, 1999) unveiled a 
view of the economic underpinnings of ancient economies in which markets 
and economic motivations played little if any role. Status and civic 
ideology governed the allocation of scarce resources. Hence, the 
application of economic theory to the ancient economy was at best a futile 
exercise and at worst a source of grave misunderstandings. By "ancient 
economy" Finley had in mind only the economy of classical civilization -- 
i.e., of the Graeco-Roman area beginning roughly in the earlier first 
millennium BC. However, Finley's perspective found completion and 
generalization in the works of the economic historian Karl Polanyi (1981).1 
Polanyi argued forcefully that the ancient Near East did not know markets 
and, like Finley, he was implacably opposed to the application of economic 
theory to ancient economic life. Thus was formed a new orthodoxy. 
Suggestions in the literature of ancient market behavior or economic 
motivation might simply be ignored or dismissed in a condescending manner 
as mere "anachronism." The latter criticism was found devastating by Greek 
and Roman scholars. 
 
The world of scholarship is rarely completely static, however. Scholars 
came forward with new evidence and new interpretations pointing to a 
significant role for markets. In their "Introduction" Scheidel and von 
Reden* explain that 
 
Critics question the real-life impact of elite mentality and identify 
apparent tensions between the historical record and the model that was 
meant to make sense of it. They tend to emphasize the considerable scale of 
economic activities (above all trade) and, make a case for significant 
economic growth in the Roman imperial period when political and fiscal 
unification boosted market exchanges. (p. 3) 
 
 
This, it may be added, represents only the tip of the critical iceberg. 
Thus, the study of the ancient economy became an "academic battleground."2 
As a result of this battle the influence of the Finley/Polanyi orthodoxy 
has unquestionably waned.3 At present the study of the ancient economy 
might be compared to a minefield, full of perils for the unsuspecting 
scholar. 
 
Thus it is most encouraging to learn from the publisher's website that the 
Greek and Roman scholars involved in the publication of _The Ancient 
Economy_ aim to move the debate beyond "partisan controversies."4 Scheidel 
and von Reden seem to second the call for studies moving the debate beyond 
the Finley/Polanyi agenda and benefiting from "the conceptual and 
analytical repertoire of modern economics" (pp. 3-4). Obviously, a new 
synthesis is badly needed even if, to begin with, it is confined to the 
Greek and Roman periods. 
 
Concerning the realities of the volume, it is certainly not reassuring 
that in the lead article (originally published in 1998), Greek specialist 
Paul Cartledge (p. 15) takes as a given Finley's view that "the categories 
of neoclassical economic analysis" have "no useful application to 'the 
ancient economy'." Cartledge goes on to consider how we should "set about 
formulating usable and useful models."5 We search his contribution vainly 
for the citation of even one example in which the predictions of economic 
theory are falsified by economic events in the Graeco-Roman economy. No 
synthesis, no new evidence and no usable new model can be detected here! 
 
Turning to the closing (previously unpublished) article, as is my wont in 
collections of this kind, Roman specialist Richard Saller (p. 253) agrees 
with Finley that modern economic theory is inappropriate for antiquity 
because of an "incomparability in economic organization."5 The problem, 
Saller suggests, is the absence in antiquity of integrated markets: Had the 
markets been fully integrated, there should not have been desperate grain 
shortages in individual cities, at the same time as other cities were well 
supplied. In such cases hungry urban dwellers did not depend solely on 
higher market prices to draw larger supplies from elsewhere in the [Roman] 
Empire. but resorted to imperial intervention.  In an integrated market, 
this sort of supervision would have been superfluous because pricing would 
have drawn grain to areas in need (p. 254 with n. 2). 
 
 
Understandably, not being imbued with the trained suspicions of the modern 
economist, it does not occur to Saller that imperial "supervision" and not 
the absence of "fully integrated markets" kept the grain away from hungry 
cities! The classic example is provided by a serious famine at Antioch in 
AD 362/3. Despite the enlightened protests of Libanius and others, Emperor 
Julian had responded to rising grain prices caused by a severe and 
prolonged drought with an edict of maximum prices and the sale of imported 
grain at prices below the market-clearing level. These well-meant but 
counterproductive measures served mainly to misallocate the available stock 
of grain (see Downey 1951: 315-19; de Jonge 1948). They also operated to 
discourage large landowners (and other speculators) from storing grain.7 
The problem here was not transport costs/fragmented markets but a much more 
significant problem: failure to understand the economic facts of life.8 
 
The remainder of Saller's contribution includes some cautionary 
observations on the scale of Roman economic growth. The ancients did of 
course accumulate material and human capital and they introduced important 
technical innovations. Clearly, the industrial era's increased reliance on 
scientific knowledge and its increased range and variety of fixed capital 
goods have steeply accelerated the rate of technical progress and material 
growth. It must not be overlooked, however, that dramatic improvements in 
living standards are attainable through improvements in economic 
organization. The evidence demonstrates that ancient civilizations 
experienced lengthy periods of market activity and prosperity, including 
even affluence, interspersed with periods of pervasive economic regulation 
by the state and, ultimately, economic retrogression. There can be no 
doubt, for example, that something very important happened to Roman living 
standards between Romulus and Remus and Diocletian! 
 
Perhaps there is more evidence of a move beyond partisan controversy 
towards a new synthesis in some of the contributions positioned between 
Cartledge and Saller. I proceed selectively and begin with a useful, 
previously published article by historian Reger because of its possible 
bearing on the question of integrated markets raised by Saller. Reger 
compares time-series of prices for a number of imported commodities (oil, 
perfume, papyrus, pitch). The price data are taken from priestly 
inscriptions on the island of Delos dating to the Hellenistic period in the 
third and second centuries BC. The prices of the various commodities 
display markedly different patterns. This finding is understood by Scheidel 
and von Reden (pp. 133-34) to undermine the view that the Hellenistic 
market was integrated (Reger 145). The assumption underlying this 
conclusion seems to be that economic integration requires prices to be 
determined by "general economic trends" and/or "broader interregional 
developments" meaning, apparently, that all prices must change in the same 
direction. Have Scheidel and von Reden identified price inflation/deflation 
with economic integration? Obviously, integration across spatially distant 
markets is quite consistent with an unchanged general level of prices 
combined with pronounced changes in relative prices -- i.e., perfume rises 
in price, oil prices decline. Indeed, such changes are commonplace in the 
contemporary economy and in no way indicate an absence of integrated 
markets. 
 
The beginning of a trend toward synthesis can indeed be seen in the 
(previously published) contribution by the French historian Andreau. I 
especially appreciated his suggestion that 
 
To contrast, term by term, everything pre-industrial with everything 
modern, and endlessly to scour antiquity for all possible and imaginable 
signs of archaism, results in a very reductionist view of history. Besides, 
whether deliberate or not, such an approach has the effect of providing 
present-day institutions and situations with an intellectual justification 
which they do not always merit, and of strengthening our reassuring (but 
illusory) impression that they are eternal, or at least immortal, since we 
have now entered modernity (p. 35).9 
 
 
While there is room for disagreement, Andreau's article merits close and 
respectful attention. 
 
A (previously published) article by archaeologist Halstead also is helpful. 
He sees "famine-brokering" as a partial answer to "what is arguably the 
most important problem in the ancient economy 'how did rich Greeks and 
Romans in classical antiquity acquire their wealth?'" (p. 68) Selling 
stored grain on the market in periods of exceptionally high prices "may 
well hold the key to the original emergence of a rich minority, _given that 
current ancient historical orthodoxy seems ... to have ruled out all the 
obvious alternatives_" (p. 69) (emphasis added). Of course, the "obvious 
alternatives" for becoming wealthy would be reinstated in any new 
synthesis! Thus, archaeologist Hitchner (p. 76) in his discussion of growth 
in the olive oil industry in the Roman provinces of North Africa observes 
 
 
the proliferation of small farms with one or two presses often in close 
proximity to oileries, and frequently on agricultural marginal lands.... 
That is, the decision to construct a large stone lever press ... 
particularly when much more modest means of extracting oil for subsistence 
needs were available, implies that surplus oil production was the ultimate 
objective of the small farm occupants. Although the capital for these 
presses is likely, in many instances, to have come from the owners of the 
nearby oilieries interested in the oleocultural development of marginal 
lands in or around their estates, we may also see in these arrangements _an 
effort by the farms' occupants, whether independent small-holders, free 
tenants or even slaves, to better their lot_ (emphasis added). 
 
 
Let it be noted that Hitchner published these words in 1993 when proponents 
of the idea that members of the ancient public might become rich by means 
of productive activity were still likely to risk being derided as 
"anachronistic."10 With respect to the sources of Athenian wealth in the 
fourth century BC Osborne (pp. 128-30) tentatively raises the 
possibilities, "against firmly held modern convictions," that manufacture 
was of some importance and that agriculture was actually profitable. 
 
_The Ancient Economy_, much to my surprise, actually does include a number 
of contributions (Andreau, Halstead, Hitchner plus the "Introduction") that 
move the discussion beyond partisan controversy toward a new synthesis. The 
volume has the additional merit of bringing together in one place valuable 
previously published articles by Hopkins, Panella/Tchernia, and Rathbone. 
On the other hand, the articles by Saller and, especially, Cartledge cling 
to the Finley/Polanyi orthodoxy. Their strategic placement in the book, 
first and last chapters, betrays a serious tension in the conception of the 
editors. To conclude, this is a collection that scholars of the ancient 
world should be pleased to have in their libraries. 
 
I do have one strong complaint. The editors (p. 4) note that "It goes 
without saying that it is impossible for a collection of this kind to cover 
all the bases." Agreed, but why in a volume devoted to economic history do 
we find classicists, historians, archaeologists and even a philosopher but 
not a single contribution by a professional economist? The omission is 
glaring and revealing. 
 
Notes: 
 
*About the Editors: Walter Scheidel, formerly Moses and Mary Finley 
Research Fellow of Darwin College, Cambridge, currently teaches Ancient 
History at the University of Chicago; Sitta von Reden is Senior Lecturer in 
Classics and Ancient History at the University of Bristol. 
 
1. I have relied upon Polanyi's posthumously published manuscript entitled 
_The Livelihood of Man_ (1981). The editor of this volume, Harry W. 
Pearson, has included material on Polanyi's life and has contributed a 
useful introduction citing Polanyi's major publications and placing his 
thought in perspective. 
 
2. The "Suggestions for further Reading" include recent contributions on 
both sides of the controversy. 
 
3. Interestingly, as their empirical base deteriorated some scholars loyal 
to this "primitivist/substantivist" school began to denigrate the use of 
empirical evidence and, more and more, to stress the importance of "erudite 
models" (see note 6 below). Indeed, even Finley (1985: 182) in "Further 
Thoughts," appealed to historical and anthropological/sociological "models" 
as opposed to "the continual evocation of individual 'facts'." 
 
4. http://www.eup.ed.ac.uk/cgi/odbic.exe?input=NewWeb/Books/2175.htm 
 
5. In modern economic models are conceptual structures capable of being 
manipulated to make predictions, which may be tested against empirical 
evidence. For Finley/Polanyi scholars, however, a model is "a heuristic 
device for organizing data into an intelligible whole" (Stager 2001: 625) 
As Finley (1985: 182) explained in "Further Thoughts," "models" are 
"valuable in obscuring incidental detail and in allowing fundamental 
aspects of reality to appear." "Model" serves as an objective-sounding name 
for _a priori_ positions that are employed to sift, shape, interpret or 
avoid the evidence. 
 
6. With two exceptions the articles included in _The Ancient Economy_ were 
originally published elsewhere. The editors contribute an introduction and 
chapter commentaries. With one exception the contributions are authored by 
classicists, historians and archaeologists. The exception is a reprinted 
contribution by philosopher Scott Meikle who, while critical of modern 
economic theory, is quite adept at manipulating the Marxist categories of 
"use value" and "exchange value." 
 
7. Halstead (p. 69) notes that the Roman writer Varro advised landowners to 
store grain in order to take advantage of high market prices in times of 
famine. 
 
8.Readers interested in market integration in the Roman world might consult 
Temin (2001). 
 
9. One might consider in the light of Andreau's remarks Douglass North's 
(1991: 98) pursuit of the "Holy Grail" of a once-and-for-all incremental 
evolution of efficient institutions. 
 
10. Hitchner (pp. 80-81) was well aware of the professional risk he was 
taking in citing empirical evidence for significant growth in the Roman 
economy. 
 
References: 
 
Downey, Glanville (1951). "The Economic Crisis at Antioch under Julian the 
Apostate." In P.R. Coleman-Norton (editor), _Studies in Roman Economic and 
Social History_. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 312- 21. 
 
Finley, Moses (1973, 1985, 1999). _The Ancient Economy_. Berkeley: 
University of California Press. 
 
de Jonge, P. (1948). "Scarcity of Corn and Corn Prices in Ammianus 
Marcellinus." _Mnemosyne_, 1, 238-45. 
 
North, Douglass C. (1991). "Institutions." _Journal of Economic 
Perspectives_, 5, 97-112. 
 
Polanyi, Karl (1981). _The Livelihood of Man_. Harry W. Pearson (editor). 
New York: Academic. 
 
Stager. Lawrence E. (2001). "Port Power in the Early and the Middle Bronze 
Age: The Organization of Maritime Trade and Hinterland Production." In 
Samuel R. Wolff (editor), _Studies in the Archaeology of Israel and 
Neighboring Lands_. Chicago: Oriental Institute, 625-38. 
 
Temin, Peter (2001), "A Market Economy in the Early Roman Empire." _Journal 
of Roman Studies_, 91, 169-81. 
 
Suggestions for Further Reading: 
 
Bleiberg, Edward (1995). "The Economy of Ancient Egypt." In Jack M. Sasson, 
John Baines, Gary Beckman, and Karen S. Rubinson (editors), _Civilizations 
of the Ancient Near East_, Vol. III. New York: Scribner's Sons, 1373-85. 
 
Cartledge, Paul, Edward E. Cohen, and Lin Foxhall (editors) (2002). _Money, 
Labour and Land: Approaches to the Economies of Ancient Greece_. London: 
Routledge. 
 
Castle, Edward W (1992). "Shipping and Trade in Ramesside Egypt." _Journal 
of the Economic and Social History of the Orient_, 35, 239-77. 
 
Cohen, Edward E. (1992). _Athenian Economy and Society: A Banking 
Perspective_. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. 
 
Dercksen, Jan Gerrit (editor) (1999). _Trade and Finance in Ancient 
Mesopotamia_. Leiden: Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut te 
Instanbul. 
 
Donlan, Walter (forthcoming). "Homer and Hesiod on Commerce and Trade". In 
Rollinger and Ulf (editors), _Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient 
World_. 
 
Engels, Donald (1990). _Roman Corinth: An Alternative Model for the 
Classical City_. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 
 
Figueira, Thomas J. (1984). "Karl Polanyi and Ancient Greek Trade: The Port 
of Trade." _Ancient World_, 10, 15-30. 
 
Greene, Kevin (2000). "Technological Innovation and Economic Progress in 
the Ancient World: M.I. Finley Re-considered." _Economic History Review_, 
53, 29-59. 
 
Hudson, Michael and Baruch A. Levine (editors) (1999). _Urbanization and 
Land Ownership in the Ancient Near East_. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Peabody 
Museum of Archaeology and Ethnology, Harvard University. 
 
Hudson, Michael and Marc Van De Mieroop (editors) (2002). _Debt and 
Economic Renewal in the Ancient Near East_. Bethesda, Maryland: CDL Press. 
 
Mattingly, David .J. (1988). "Oil for Export? A Comparison of Libyan, 
Spanish, and Tunisian Olive Oil Production in the Roman Empire." _Journal 
of Roman Archaeology_, 1, 33-56. 
 
Mattingly, David J., David Stone, Lea Sterling and Nejib Ben Lazreg (2001). 
"Leptimus (Tunisia): A 'Producer' City?." In David J. Mattingly and John 
Salmon (editors), _Economies Beyond Agriculture in the Classical World_. 
London: Routledge, 66-89. 
 
Menu, Bernadette (2001a). "Economy: Overview." In Redford (editor), _The 
Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Egypt_. Vol. 1, 422-6. 
 
Menu, Bernadette (2001b). "Economy: Private Sector". In Redford (editor), 
_The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Egypt_. Vol. 1, 430-3. 
 
Millett, Paul (1991). _Lending and Borrowing in Ancient Athens_. Cambridge: 
Cambridge University Press. 
 
Olivier, Jean-Pierre (1987). "Des Extraits De Contrats De Vente D'Esclaves 
Dans Les Tablettes De Knossos." In John T. Killen, José L. Melena, and 
Jean-Pierre Olivier (editors), _Studies in Mycenaean and Classical Greek_. 
Salamanca: Universidad de Salamanca, 479-98. 
 
Purcell, Nicholas (1990). "Mobility and the Polis." In Oswyn Murray and 
Simon Price (editors), _The Greek City from Homer to Alexander_. Oxford: 
Oxford University Press, 29-58. 
 
Redford, Donald B. (editor) (2001). _The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient 
Egypt_. 3 volumes. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 
 
Rollinger, Robert and Christoph Ulf (editors) (forthcoming). _Commerce and 
Monetary Systems in the Ancient World_ (5th International MELAMMU 
Conference, Innsbruck Oct. 3rd-8th 2002). 
 
Silver, Morris (1995). _Economic Structures of Antiquity_. Westport, 
Connecticut: Greenwood Press. 
 
Silver, Morris (forthcoming). "Modern Ancients". In Rollinger and Ulf 
(editors), _Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient World_. 
 
 
Morris Silver is Professor Emeritus of Economics in the City College of the 
City University of New York. His most recent publications about ancient 
economies are _Taking Ancient Mythology Economically_ (Leiden: Brill, 1992) 
and _Economic Structures of Antiquity_ (Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood 
Press, 1995). "Modern Ancients" is forthcoming in Rollinger and Ulf 
(editors), _Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient World _, Fifth 
Annual Melammu Conference 2002. Professor Silver maintains a website on 
"Ancient Economies" at http://sondmor.tripod.com/index-html. 
 
Copyright (c) 2002 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied 
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and 
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator 
([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2850; Fax: 513-529-3308). 
Published by EH.Net (January 2003). All EH.Net reviews are archived at 
http://www.eh.net/BookReview 
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2