------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (September 2007)
Diane Coyle, _The Soulful Science: What Economists Really Do and Why
It Matters_. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2007. vii +
255 pp. $28 (cloth), ISBN: 978-0-691-12513-8.
Reviewed for EH.NET by John A. MacDonald, Department of Economics,
Wake Forest University.
With the title "The Soulful Science: What Economists Really Do and
Why it Matters," Diane Coyle surely inspires interest in economists
and non-economists alike. The point of her book is presumably to
rally economists while explaining the importance of our discipline to
anyone else who views it with suspicion. Unfortunately, while the
book is thoughtfully presented and thoroughly researched, the
presentation of this point is largely obscured by some rather dense
prose. But if the reader gets past this drawback, the underlying
message becomes clear: economics is more than you think, and yes, it
really does matter.
To make her case, Coyle begins with a chapter devoted entirely to the
seemingly innocuous topic of data. The ensuing discussion reveals how
economists have risen to the enormous task of accumulating and
reconstructing all sorts of data. The central character in this
discussion, economic historian Angus Maddison, is known for having
estimated GDP and growth rates for almost two hundred nations dating
back to the year 1000 A.D. Incredible efforts like Maddison's enable
researchers to tackle questions that, in the absence of data, were
essentially impossible to answer. Hence, economists provide the
extremely vital service of collecting and maintaining important data
sets.
The next thing economists do, once the data are in place, is test
theories and refine their tools of analysis. With this in mind, the
second and third chapters are primarily concerned with the evolution
of post-neoclassical endogenous growth theory. Along with the advent
of powerful computers and increasingly sophisticated econometrics,
the massive data expansion has enabled empiricists to treat
previously exogenous variables as endogenous. This has led to both a
testing of long-accepted growth theories (i.e., Solow's model) and
the development of new ones (i.e., human capital and technology
growth models). Such theoretical developments in turn enable
policymakers to better address - and potentially fix - vexing social
issues, such as poverty. Clearly the implications of these synergies
are profound.
At this point, assuming that the reader has developed a strong grasp
of "why it matters," Coyle shifts the focus of the discussion
inwards. She devotes the middle three chapters (4-6) to an
introspective examination of several key assumptions generally made
by economists. For example, while economists have long believed that
per capita GDP is an appropriate indicator of well-being, many are
questioning it as a truly useful measurement of "happiness." Possible
substitutes include the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW),
the Genuine Progress Index (GPI), and the Human Development Index
(HDI). Each is constructed with emphasis on a particular aspect
considered important to its promoters. However, any such emphasis is
inherently subjective, revealing biases that can be exploited to fit
just about anyone's agenda. After much consideration, Coyle concludes
that GDP is a pretty good measurement of well-being after all, and
that any permutations that push us away from it unnecessarily damage
consensus (and, therefore, our collective credibility).
Not all innovative work is viewed so skeptically, however. Chapter 5
challenges the assumption that all people are rational, utility
maximizing robots. New models and policy angles instead suggest that
people are, in a sense, predictably unpredictable. For instance,
normal people exhibit inertia to the point where they take what's
given to them most of the time, even when they know such behavior
isn't rational. A good example is "opt-out" versus "opt-in"
retirement savings programs: opt-out participation is in the 70-80%
range, while opt-in participation for identical programs is in the
20-30% range. We also have a problem getting normal people to be
objective in the first place: they often get set in their opinions
and refuse to believe the truth even when it stares them in the face.
Paying attention to such things helps keep models as realistic as
possible, which helps maximize the persuasiveness of their
conclusions.
Shifting gears one last time, Coyle concludes her book with three
chapters intended to bring together "the social nature of the economy
and the human nature of the individuals making up society." Chapter 7
provides a convincing account of evolutionary economics: why markets
are Darwinian, how economics influenced Charles Darwin, and how
Darwin, in turn, influenced economics. She links the concept of
natural selection to the gradual transformation of markets over time.
Successful firms are much like successful biological entities in that
they persevere as a result of gradual mutation/innovation, constant
adaptation, and chance. Joseph Schumpeter is oft-discussed here as a
sort of visionary user of evolutionary principles, being among the
first modern economists to really embrace dynamic questions. But
evolutionary economics has only recently caught on because, as Coyle
points out, it fell out of fashion after WWII due to its association
with the Nazis (through eugenics). Nevertheless, she sums up its
reemerging appeal by striking a centuries-old nostalgic chord: "the
attraction of evolutionary theory is the absence of a plan, a
designer, a central organizing intelligence - the invisible hand, the
emergent, self-organizing economic order." Despite commanding a
minority interest in economics, it is hard to disagree with her
conclusion that "any economist who studies industrial organization
and technical change clearly has a strong intuition that it is an
evolutionary process."
While these topics might sound very interesting, they suffer from a
lack of obvious cohesion when presented one after another in the
book. Ironically, one might say "The Soulful Science" lacks soul:
there is no single, central, pervasive point that inspires much
emotional excitement. This is a problem because the title of the book
would seem to suggest otherwise. The problem is compounded by the
strange sense that "what economists really do" is nothing more than
deal, around the clock, with data: they collect it, construct it,
argue about how to interpret it, devise complex models around it -
undeniably important stuff, but not exactly soulful. Further,
although one gets the feeling throughout that there must be a punch
line somewhere in the text revealing "why it matters," it doesn't
materialize until the third to last page. This is strange because it
is arguably the most important point of the book. Nonetheless, it is
summarized by Coyle as follows: "The availability of solid empirical
evidence on an array of social issues is?going to make economics very
controversial. ... A lot of sacred political cows are heading for the
slaughterhouse?" In other words, the mounting evidence provided by,
analyzed by, and interpreted by economists will eventually, when
combined with the massive proliferation of information, lead to
incredible political momentum towards all sorts of change. THAT's why
it matters. Why did it take 253 pages to say so?
In short, the book is a good reference for economists interested in
how the discipline has flourished in the past thirty years or so. It
might also be appropriate for economic history courses that focus on
the modern era. But the length and editing make "The Soulful Science"
unlikely to capture the attention of casual readers.
John A. MacDonald recently defended his dissertation, "An Examination
of Airline Pricing: Testing the Effects of Mergers and Uncertainty on
Average Fares and Dispersion," at the University of North Carolina --
Chapel Hill.
Copyright (c) 2007 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).
Published by EH.Net (September 2007). All EH.Net reviews are archived
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
[log in to unmask]
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review
|