------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (September 2008)
Arvind Panagariya, _India: The Emerging Giant_. New York: Oxford
University Press, 2008. xxx + 514 pp., $40 (cloth), ISBN:
978-0-19-531503-5.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Arjun Jayadev, Department of Economics,
University of Massachusetts -- Boston.
Arvind Panagariya?s book represents an important contribution to the
voluminous literature on India?s economy. While there has been no
shortage of scholarship on the subject -- one of the favorite countries
of study for development economists worldwide- there have been few
authors who have attempted the ambitious task of providing a
comprehensive survey of the trajectory of the economy and the history of
macroeconomic policies in a single volume. Panagariya?s lifetime of
research on the subject makes him well placed to tell this story. The
depth of this knowledge is certainly evident throughout this book, and
most tellingly in his description of the evolution of various policies
in the history of independent India. Yet, despite the considerable
weightiness of this work, its central message is rather musty and the
uneven and slanted marshaling of debates will do little to convince
those who are less well inclined to the common liberal narrative of
India?s growth pattern.
The morality tale of the fall and resurrection of market-oriented
policies and the rescue of India from poverty and moribund growth when
policy makers turned away from dirigisme is the backdrop for the
analysis in this book. In Panagariya?s retelling, the modern economic
history of India is a play in four acts: 1951-65 -- a period of relative
liberalism under Nehru; 1965-81 -- a period where ?Socialism Strikes
with a Vengeance?; 1981-88 -- ?Liberalization by Stealth?; and 1988-2006
-- ?The Triumph of Liberalization.? The general story is told in the
first part of the book and is by now well known and standard. What is
striking, however, is how ideologically uncompromising, even stubborn,
the author is in the defense of this narrative. Panagariya?s odd
periodization can be seen, for example, as a response to arguments made
by Dani Rodrik, Arvind Subramanian and Atul Kohli that the period
1980-91 should properly be seen as the beginning of the productivity
surge in India. Panagariya?s annexation of the high growth rates from
1988-1991 to the era of liberalization (a full three years before its
official start) makes the overall growth rates seem that much higher in
the latter period. There is no compelling reason given for this maneuver
and it is one of several dubious presentations of evidence or
mischaracterizations of opponents throughout the book.
Consider as an example, the chapter on South Korea and India. Panagariya
does no justice to the arguments of what he calls the revisionists. For
example, he attacks Dani Rodrik?s (1995) argument that the initial
impetus to Korean growth could not have been export orientation (since
incentives to export were not high enough in the 1960s) and more likely
investment coordination and an increase in incentives to private
investment began the cycle of growth. Rodrik argues that the
contribution of exports to overall growth was low until the 1970s.
Panagariya?s ?proof? via an argument of Westphal and Kim that exports
also had an effect on investment growth is in no way a refutation of
anything that is claimed by Rodrik. An examination of Rodrik?s paper
shows much greater care with the arguments than Panagariya takes.
Furthermore, the fundamental claim of the revisionists is that there was
substantial dirigisme in the Korean case -- an argument which Panagariya
does nothing to dismiss.
Another example is the treatment of regional divergence in India.
Panagariya seems to treat this as a non-issue and suggests that since
the number of poor in all regions is falling, greater effort towards
poverty reduction in the poorer states will automatically treat this.
Scholars of the Indian experience will point to two missing aspects.
First, the rate of poverty reduction has not increased in the
post-liberalization period and certainly not in the states where poverty
reduction has been most needed. Second, any effort towards poverty
reduction in these regions will likely require illiberal policies such
as increased public expenditure and directing of finance. There are
several other examples which any reader will observe.
Several large sections of the book are arguments countering the work of
more recent authors who have started to question and revise our
understanding of the policies of the pre- and post-liberalization
periods. Panagariya crosses swords with Rohini Pande and Robin Burgess
on the idea that nationalization of banks and the rural banking movement
reduced poverty; he takes issue with Petia Topalova?s finding that those
districts which imposed fewer tariffs saw slower decreases in poverty;
he takes on Nouriel Roubini?s and Richard Hemming?s contention of
fragility in India?s financial sector; he argues with Pranab Bardhan?s
characterization of the debate on labor laws and so on. While there is
nothing wrong with the robust partisanship on display, one has the
impression that he is taking on too much and as a result is too often
unconvincing. Several criticisms devolve into a criticism of
methodologies of his opponents; valuable perhaps, but rarely definitive.
The book then turns to chapters dealing with a specific topic, beginning
with the debate on poverty, inequality and reforms before considering
specific sectors of the economy such as the external sector,
agriculture, industry, health, telecommunications and so on. The
question of poverty, growth and reforms is one that is immense (for a
full, book-length treatment, see Angus Deaton and Valerie Kozel?s _Great
Indian Poverty Debate_) and Panagariya?s summary of this debate
naturally leaves much out. While his exposition has an unobjectionable
conclusion -- higher growth rates have led to lower poverty and have
been the single biggest benefit of liberalization -- he is too often
dismissive of genuine concerns of policy makers and scholars. For
example, he is scornful of those who are concerned with equity,
underscoring a narrow Paretianism at best and ?trickle down? championing
at worst that underlies his views. In Panagariya?s view (pp. 160-61),
reforms have become ?hostage to the ... pursuit of equity,? which may
have an adverse impact on growth. Best rather to trust to the
philanthropy of the super rich to reduce poverty (he cites Bhagwati?s
use of Bill Gates as an example). This is a rather strained position
considering the spending habits of India?s super rich (where the fourth
wealthiest man in the world is best known for planning to build a
billion dollar home). Other positions on poverty debates also are
equally implausible. For Panagariya there is no clear link between
India?s problem of farmer suicides and reforms (and in doing so he
ignores the findings of several researchers that increased market
orientation in agriculture, greater volatility from world prices and
lack of sources of formal debt engendered by financial reforms were
strong correlates). Instead he suggests, farmers who committed suicide
were perhaps simply of a greater ?risk taking nature? and thus were
highly indebted.
The book is at its strongest in the chapters on policy changes in the
various sectors that he tackles. There is much to be commended in these
chapters. I have not come across a single similar source with the level
of detail and historical information on the history of policy in these
sectors. This is an erudite exposition but the reader should be warned
that it does not make for casual reading. The exhausting mountain of
facts and the linear narrative are more in the mode of a textbook than a
synthetic reading in the light of an overarching theme.
As a whole then, this is an ambitious and wide ranging book and will
allow a patient reader a much greater in-depth knowledge of the ebbs and
flows of policy. It is not, however, without flaws. An ideological
fidelity can often lead to great perspicacity and allows for a new way
of thinking about a subject. One thinks of such books as Jagdish
Bhagwati and Padma Desai?s 1970 book (_Planning for Industrialization_)
which was an early critique of planning or Pranab Bardhan?s 1984 book
(_The Political Economy of Development in India_) which examined class
dynamics in India as exemplars. Those books made arguments with verve
and penetration but most importantly provided a template by which to
think about the Indian economy. In doing so they became and remain
classics. Panagariya?s book also displays an ideological affiliation but
one that that is increasingly stale. This is a pity because there are
many nuanced ways in which liberalization can be defended. In addition
it takes too many liberties in creating straw men opponents and twists
too many arguments without adequate defense to suit the required
conclusion. As such, despite its undoubted scholarly strength, it is
unlikely to make anyone think differently.
Arjun Jayadev is a Post Doctoral Fellow at the Committee on Global
Thought, Columbia University as well as Assistant Professor of Economics
at the University of Massachusetts Boston. He has published articles
recently in the _Journal of Development Economics_, _Economics Letters_,
and the _Cambridge Journal of Economics_. Arjun.jayadev at umb.edu
Copyright (c) 2008 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the
author and the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net
Administrator (administrator at eh.net; Telephone: 513-529-2229). Published
by EH.Net (September 2008). All EH.Net reviews are archived at
http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
EH.Net-Review at eh.net
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review
|