SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:44 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (350 lines)
------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW -------------- 
Published by EH.NET (December 2004) 
 
Mark Duckenfield, editor, _The Monetary History of Gold: A  
Documentary History, 1660-1999_. London: Pickering & Chatto, 2004.  
xix + 536 pp. =A399/$160 (hardcover), ISBN: 1-85196-785-0. 
 
Reviewed for EH.NET by Lawrence H. Officer, Department of Economics,  
University of Illinois at Chicago. 
 
                        A Review Article 
 
[This review article contains several tables, which can't be  
displayed properly in plain text.  The tables can be viewed in the  
archived copy at http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml.] 
 
A new collection of historical documents is always welcomed by  
scholars. This is especially so if the collection is theme-oriented,  
so that specialists can acquire new information or readier access to  
existing information. Therefore the present volume, presented as a  
documentary history of gold, warrants careful review. The editor,  
Mark Duckenfield, explains that the project was financed by the World  
Gold Council's Public Policy Centre "to raise awareness among  
journalists, scholars and the informed public of gold's role as a  
monetary asset" (p. xvii). This review will be concerned solely with  
the book's place in the scholarly literature. 
 
What is the World Gold Council? According to its website  
(http://www.jewelrynet.com/WorldGold/), "the World Gold Council is a  
non-profit association of the world's leading gold producers,  
established to promote the use of gold ... and its promotional  
activities cover markets representing some three quarters of the  
world's annual consumption of gold." It is interesting, therefore,  
that the volume contains no documents that deal with gold production,  
gold consumption, or gold investment. Indeed, these categories do not  
even enter the index, which, at over eleven pages, is not short. Only  
in one editorial passage does the editor discuss the role of gold as  
an investment. Duckenfield sees gold and the stock market as  
investment alternatives, and observes that "the stock market's  
decline since 1999, as well as the increase in international tensions  
as a result of the terrorist attack on the World Trade Center in New  
York on 11 September 2001 and the second Gulf War in 2003, brought a  
resurgence in the gold market as investors returned to gold as a  
traditional safe-haven in troubled times" (p. 327).  He explicitly  
states that  "gold ... [is] a non-interest bearing asset."  
Notwithstanding the sponsorship, this is a book that adopts a  
scholarly viewpoint and can be appreciated by historians. 
 
In this review the book is placed in context with existing  
collections of historical documents that have the same,  
gold-oriented, theme -- in whole or in part. These books are listed  
in Table 1, in chronological order; full citations are provided in  
the references at the end of this review. 
 
[ Table 1 is available at  
http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml#Table1 ] 
 
In terms of absolute size Duckenfield is in the middle of the pack,  
fourth out of seven in total pagination. With 100-percent devotion to  
documents, the book's relative size in this respect is shared by only  
two other collections: Huntington and Mawhinney (subsequently  
referenced as "Huntington") and the massive, four-volume work of  
Krooss. Considering the other books in Table 1, what else is in them  
apart from historical documents and associated editorial commentary?  
U.S. Senate contains proceedings of the International Monetary  
Conference of 1878. These are presented as contemporary recording  
rather than historical documentation; therefore these proceedings are  
not included in the historical document pagination. Horton and  
Laughlin are each mainly a monetary treatise. Shrigley offers  
non-document information, quantitative and qualitative, on gold and  
the Bank of England (of which, more below). It may be noted that S.  
Dana Horton, a U.S. delegate to international monetary conferences,  
not only authored and edited the historical documents in Horton  
(1887) but also had been responsible for the historical documents  
included in U.S. Senate (1879). 
 
Table 2 summarizes the anatomy of Duckenfield and the six other  
works. In Table 1 all historical documents are included to obtain the  
page count; in Table 2 only those documents that fall within  
categories covered by Duckenfield are incorporated. (These are called  
"pertinent documents," in this review.) Some judgment on the part of  
this reviewer is involved. For example, Duckenfield has one document  
pertaining to the greenback period as a suspension of specie  
payments; documents under that category are included for the other  
works. An opposite example: Duckenfield has a document on goldsmith  
banking; this reviewer judges that insufficient to incorporate the  
category "commercial banking." Again, measured by number of  
documents, Duckenfield is fourth among the seven collections. 
 
[ Table 2 is available at  
http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml#Table2 ] 
 
All the collections except Shrigley are divided into sections, some  
chronological, some by country, some by topic, as Table 2 shows. Only  
two of the works have systematic subsections. Within sections and  
subsections, ordering is uniformly chronological. Regarding editorial  
commentary, Duckenfield is unique, and deserves praise, for having  
editorial introductions in all three manifestations: for the entire  
volume, by section, and for the individual documents within each  
section. Because entries in a collected volume of documents generally  
are excerpts rather than the entire documents, this reviewer  
appreciates Duckenfield's practice of calling attention to  
non-reprinted parts of documents. 
 
The three sections of Duckenfield warrant discussion, here in the  
context of editorial commentary. The introduction to the first, "The  
Rise of the Gold Standard, 1660-1819," is concerned entirely with  
British monetary history. Duckenfield observes England's movement  
from bimetallism to a de facto gold standard in 1717. He notes the  
interruption of the Bank Restriction Period in this process. It is  
reasonable to confine discussion to Britain, because it was the only  
country on a gold standard well into the nineteenth century. However,  
it would have been in order to discuss the bimetallist systems of  
other countries. 
 
The second section, "The Heyday of the Gold Standard, 1820-1930," has  
a broader introduction, including topics such as the expansion of the  
gold standard, the price specie-flow mechanism, the U.S. shift from  
an effective silver to an effective gold standard (with the  
interruption of the greenback period), the deflation of 1873-1896,  
and London as the center of the gold standard. The end of the  
classical gold standard with World War I is noted, as is the return  
to the standard after the war. Duckenfield discusses the issue of  
convertibility but can be criticized for ignoring that of credibility  
(of countries' commitment to convertibility at the existing mint  
price), which underlay the success of the classical gold standard. 
 
In his introduction to the third section, "After the Gold Standard,  
1931-1999," Duckenfield sees a weak institutional structure as the  
cause of instability of the interwar gold standard. "Domestic social  
tensions" and the "prospect of substantial budget deficits" drove  
countries off the gold standard. War and "new social realities" meant  
that political and economic institutions that supported the gold  
standard could not overcome political demands that occurred during  
the Great Depression. Again, reference to the issue of credibility,  
now the lack thereof, in government's commitment to convertibility  
would have been in order. 
 
The introduction also discusses the International Monetary Fund, the  
role of the dollar, and the "Triffin dilemma" (the trade-off between  
liquidity and confidence). On the U.S. suspension of gold  
convertibility in 1971, Duckenfield writes: "Ironically, although it  
was the weakness of the dollar relative to gold that brought about  
the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, it was gold that was  
removed from its primary position as a monetary asset while the  
devalued dollar became even more crucial to the smooth operation of  
the international economy" (pp. 326-327). It can be argued, rather,  
that it was U.S. commitment to a fixed dollar price of gold that  
artificially made gold the first class monetary asset. 
 
Table 3 divides the pertinent documents of each work into  
chronological sections (pre 1820, 1820-1930, post-1930) corresponding  
to the Duckenfield partitioning, except that Horton's original  
partitioning is retained, because it is so close to that of  
Duckenfield chronologically. Of course, the four documents antedating  
Shrigley lack the third (post 1930) section, because of the date of  
publication. 
 
[ Table 3 is available at  
http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml#Table3 ] 
 
What are the components of official versus private documents?  
Official documents consist of country and international items.  
Country official documents include acts, resolutions, announcements,  
reports, memoranda, communications, statements, declarations,  
representations, speeches, notes on petitions, parliamentary diaries,  
proclamations, mint correspondence, and press conferences.  
International documents (all official) consist of treaties,  
conventions, resolutions, agreements, press releases, communiqu=E9s,  
and decisions. Private documents include treatises, books, pamphlets,  
diaries, discourses, petitions, speeches, reports, correspondence,  
memoirs, newspaper articles, and memoranda. 
 
As one would expect in collections of documents, the vast majority of  
documents are official, in all the works. Duckenfield is unique in  
having private documents constitute a significant proportion -- over  
one-third the total number -- of documents in the pre-1820 period. 
 
Table 4 offers an alternative division of pertinent documents -- by  
country (Britain, United States, other countries), with international  
as a separate category. For private documents, the subject country is  
taken. For official documents, the country category is the country of  
the official document rather than the subject country or countries.  
All seven works concentrate on Britain and/or the United States.  
Huntington and Krooss deal only with the United States, Shrigley only  
with Britain. Laughlin has U.S., other-country, and international --  
but not British -- documents; while Horton includes only British and  
international documents. The only works with documents in each  
category are the earliest and latest: U.S. Senate and Duckenfield. As  
would be expected, U.S. Senate has somewhat more U.S. than British  
documents overall (but not for the pre-1820 period). 
 
[ Table 4 is available at  
http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml#Table4 ] 
 
One would predict a balanced British/U.S. division on the part of  
Duckenfield, given that neither the book-title nor the sponsor is  
specific-country oriented. Then one would be disappointed, because a  
British emphasis is present in every period. The asymmetry is  
apparent in several ways: 
1. There are nine documents of the Bank Restriction Period but only  
three from the greenback period and nothing on other U.S. suspensions  
of specie payments. 
2. There is an entry for the Bank of England charter, but not for the  
Federal Reserve Act. 
3. There are more entries for Acts of Parliament than for U.S. legislatio= 
n. 
4. The British Coinage Act of 1870 is reprinted in full; not so the  
U.S. Coinage Act of 1873, which admittedly is a longer Act. 
 
In fairness to Duckenfield, it should be noted that, while Winston  
Churchill's famous Budget Speech of 1925 returning the United Kingdom  
to the gold standard is excerpted, William Jennings Bryan's at least  
equally famous "Cross of Gold" Speech is reprinted in full. Also,  
there are many entries involving U.S. abandonment of the gold  
standard in 1933-1934. 
 
Notwithstanding the generally British orientation of Duckenfield,  
Horton is the better source for material on the history of the guinea  
-- perhaps the most famous coin in British history, and, along with  
the (new) sovereign introduced in 1817, one of the country's two most  
important coins. Only seven of Horton's 31 documents on the guinea  
are included in Duckenfield. The guinea is notable as a coin for two  
reasons. First, its initial value of 20 shillings corresponded to the  
pound sterling. Interestingly, the guinea was not the first coin with  
this property; that distinction belongs to the old sovereign,  
introduced in 1489. Second, the fineness of 11/12th was firmly  
established with the guinea (and continuing with the new sovereign);  
but again the guinea was not the first coin with that fineness (that  
honor belonging to the crown in 1526). 
 
Shrigley, totally specialized on Britain, has a specific theme within  
gold. She writes: "The purpose of this collection of documents is to  
show the official position of gold as a marketable commodity from the  
Incorporation of the Bank of England to the Gold Standard (Amendment)  
Act of 1931" (p. vii). Of her 20 documents, 12 are not in Duckenfield. 
 
Table 5 breaks down the "other-countries" category of Table 4 into  
specific countries. Duckenfield does not provide a rationale for his  
concentration on Switzerland in the 1920-1930 and post-1930 periods  
in this respect, nor for inclusion of material on countries such as  
Chile and Yugoslavia post-1930. It is also arguable that France and  
Germany deserve greater attention than all three works give these  
countries. 
 
[ Table 5 is available at  
http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml#Table5 ] 
 
Table 6, similarly, partitions the "international" category of Table  
4. Duckenfield can perhaps be criticized for neglecting the  
international monetary conferences of the nineteenth century. Yet he  
deserves praise for including the, post-World War I, Treaty of  
Versailles -- relevant because of the gold-denomination of the  
monetary obligations imposed on Germany. 
 
[ Table 6 is available at  
http://www.eh.net/bookreviews/library/0878.shtml#Table6 ] 
 
Duckenfield deserves praise on a number of counts. First, for some  
documents, the contents of appendices are listed. (Indeed, that is  
sometimes the full text of the entry.) These contents can be useful  
references for the scholar. Second, Duckenfield makes use of  
generally neglected sources: Bank of England archives and the House  
of Lords Record Office. Third, some documents may be new to  
historians. Examples: a "confidential telegram" (one of many) sent on  
September 20, 1931, from the Bank of England to domestic and foreign  
correspondents; the Rothschild letter on fixing the price of gold in  
1939, just prior to World War II. 
 
A serious limitation of the Duckenfield volume is the neglect of  
quantitative information. Only three documents have a quantitative  
aspect: the original Articles of Agreement of the IMF, which contains  
the list of country quotas; the IMF Executive Board decision on the  
Smithsonian Agreement which lists exchange rates for member  
countries; and, perhaps most interesting to historians because  
probably not available elsewhere, three documents from the Bank of  
England's Archives providing data on gold holdings of countries  
occupied by Germany, in 1940. In contrast, the documents in U.S.  
Senate contain many useful tables on U.S. exchange rates, gold and  
silver prices, and coinage. 
 
Shrigley presents several useful time series (which are not included  
in the list of her documents, in Tables 2-4): the annual gold-silver  
market price ratio, 1867-1932; the London market price of gold,  
annual 1870-1932, daily 1919-1925; and the London market price of  
silver, monthly 1833-1933. The last is an insert at the end of the  
book, and includes also annual data on silver coined in England, the  
amount of bills and telegraphic transfers drawn in England on Indian  
governments, exports of silver to the East, imports of silver,  
average Bank Rate, and remarks (generally historical). It is a large  
and impressive table, which, unfortunately, because not attached to  
the volume, may be missing from many copies. Not a time series, but  
nevertheless useful, is a list of Governors of the Bank of England  
from inception to 1920, along with dates of service. 
 
In conclusion, the Duckenfield volume is a useful addition to  
collections of historical documents on gold, and would be best  
utilized by scholars in conjunction with existing works of a similar  
ilk. 
 
References: 
 
Horton, S. Dana (1887). _The Silver Pound and England's Monetary  
Policy since the Restoration, together with the History of the  
Guinea, illustrated by contemporary documents_. London: Macmillan. 
 
Huntington, A. T., and Robert J. Mawhinney, eds. (1910). _Laws of the  
United States Concerning Money, Banking, and Loans, 1778-1909_.  
National Monetary Commission, Senate Document No. 580, 61st Congress,  
2nd session. Washington: Government Printing Office. 
 
Krooss, Herman E., ed. (1969). _Documentary History of Banking and  
Currency in the United States_, four volumes. New York: Chelsea House  
in association with McGraw-Hill. 
 
Lauglin, J. Laurence (1896). _The History of Bimetallism in the  
United States_. New York: D. Appleton. 
 
Shrigley, Irene, ed. (1935). _The Price of Gold: Documents  
Illustrating the Statutory Control through the Bank of England of the  
Market Price of Gold, 1694-1931_. London: P.S. King & Son. 
 
U.S. Senate (1879). _International Monetary Conference=8Aheld=8Ain Paris,= 
  
in August 1878, under the auspices of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs  
of the Republic of France_. Senate Executive Document No. 58, 45th  
Congress, 3rd session. Washington: Government Printing Office. 
 
 
Lawrence H. Officer is Professor of Economics at University of  
Illinois at Chicago. As Editor, Special Projects, EH.Net, he has  
recently completed "What Is Its Relative Value in U.K. Pounds," a  
calculator available on the EH.Net website  
(http://www.eh.net/hmit/ukcompare). 
 
Copyright (c) 2004 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be  
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to  
the author and EH.Net. For other permission, please contact the  
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).  
Published by EH.Net (December 2004). All EH.Net reviews are archived  
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview. 
 
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW  -------------- 
EH.Net-Review mailing list 
[log in to unmask] 
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review 
 
 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2