SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Mohammad Gani)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:51 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (176 lines)
  
   Happy Reading to the London Reading Group on Keynes's General Theory!  
  
  
   I bought my first copy of this great book (trading off 21 meals) in 1972 in  
   Dhaka. Bangladesh had just emerged from a genocidal liberation war and we  
   were in a hero-worship mood, and Keynes seemed to us like the great warrior  
   who battled the genocide-like problem of mass unemployment. But we soon  
   found what Samuelson described: this book was hard to read.  We learned what  
   Keynes said from Alvin Hansen and Kenneth Kurihara and others. As I lost my  
   books when I moved from Dhaka to New York to Boston to Washington to Atlanta  
   to Toronto, I kept buying copies of the book, and with the same frustration:  
   how do you read what Keynes wrote? I Bbught the same book five times over,  
   but could never finish reading it.  Can the London group finish reading it?  
  
  
   I guess somebody should prepare a readable version of the book. Here are  
   some suggestions for the reading group.  
  
  
   1. What is GT about? Suppose that it is about market-clearing, namely, how  
   can the economy reach a state of full employment such as when the supply of  
   labor is matched by demand? To find what may determine full employment, we  
   may also discover what may deter full employment: what could prevent the  
   market from clearing?  
  
  
   2. Unsaying Says Law? The new generation of readers may approach the issue  
   of market clearing with a two dimensional concept of market equilibrium. The  
   first dimension is the quantitative matching: the quantity supplied must  
   match the quantity demanded. Classical theory had two ingredients to deal  
   with this, but the two were not modeled compactly, leaving much looseness  
   that ultimately assailed it.  The quantitative matching relies on the price  
   flexibility mechanism, and also involves an equality of value of equivalence  
   to achieve balance of payment or balance of incomes. The price flexibility  
   mechanism says that if the demand is not equal to supply, the price must  
   change such that demands and supplies will change until they become equal.  
   The other part is Says Law that ought to have said that the value of what  
   one sells must be equal to the value of what one gets in exchange. But Says  
   Law was unclear and that doomed the theory of market clearing through price  
   and  output adjustments. The assault on Says Law was bound to invite a  
   backlash.  
  
  
   But why was Keynes talking about money then? Was he groping to find an  
   articulation  for  the second dimension of market clearing? The second  
   dimension is that in equilibrium, the kinds of goods must match too.  After  
   being sabotaged by Jevons, the idea of double coincidence as an equilibrium  
   condition lost its legitimate place and gave rise to groping.  One could not  
   see why money was in the picture without grasping the second dimension  
   (matching of kinds). Had this been clear, Keynes would be understood most  
   easily. Here is how I would reread Keynes.  
  
  
   First, let us bust Says Law by showing that even when demand is equal to  
   supply for every good at the equilibrium price (so that income is equal to  
   expenditure for every agent), the market may still not clear. Suppose that  
   John has 1 dollar of x to sell and wants to buy 1 dollar of y from Paul.  
   However, Paul does not want to buy 1 dollar of x, from John but wants to buy  
   1 dollar of z from Tim. And Tim wants to buy 1 dollar of x against the sale  
   of 1 dollar of z.  Now, there is a set of prices at which the values of x, y  
   and z reach equilibrium; and the income for each agent is exactly equal to  
   the expenditure. Yet there is no trade, because barter is not possible. John  
   cannot sell x and buy y directly, because Paul refuses to buy x against y.  
   Paul cannot sell y to buy z, because Tim refuses to buy y against z. And Tim  
   cannot buy x for z, because John does not want to buy z.  
  
  
   The solution is the use of external money as a device to transfer claims. An  
   outside senior must issue money such that John will deliver x to Tim and get  
   money instead of z. He will then buy y with money instead of with x. Paul  
   will get money for y, and then get z for money but not for y. The real goods  
   are of the wrong kind to serve as means of payment, so that everybody here  
   must pay with money instead of with the real good, even though money is just  
   a device to allow the owner to claim the right kind of good.  
  
  
   The second dimension is the matching of kinds. This is achieved by creating  
   double  coincidence  between  money and the real good, and this double  
   coincidence is artificial.  Thus John really does not demand money, but  
   demands y, and yet he pretends to demand money when he sells x to Tim for  
   money. The double coincidence between x and money is a necessary condition  
   for the sale of x.  There is no market clearing except with money here. Even  
   though  z  really  pays for x, z cannot pay for x directly: it must be  
   converted into y to properly compensate the seller of x. This conversion is  
   done by the use of money as a device to transfer value, and not a device to  
   store value.  
  
  
   If one sees this example, one can relate it to Keyness idea of multiplier.  
   If one dollar changes hands 3 times over, then the failure to issue 1 dollar  
   will disable trade worth 3 dollars.  
  
  
   3. Price theory of monetary theory? The monetarist counter-revolution and  
   the rise of real business cycle there would not occur had Keynes steered  
   clear of price theory (first dimension) and instead embarked on monetary  
   theory  to uncover the second dimension of market equilibrium.  I have  
   decided to forgive myself for feeling utterly confused: what is Keynes  
   doing? Is he studying price theory or is he doing monetary theory? What have  
   the wage rate or the interest rate to do with market clearing other than the  
   way classical theory described price-quantity adjustments?   In short, why  
   bring money in the discussion? Wage rigidity, money illusion, and liquidity  
   trap are all matters of price theory, oops, are they matters of monetary  
   theory?  
  
  
   The key is to distinguish between ability to buy as given by equivalence  
   (Says Law) from ability to pay as given by money. The term effective demand  
   seems to be groping for this distinction.  
  
  
   For example, John has 1 dollar of x and wants to buy 1 dollar of y, he has  
   the  ability to buy y, that is, he has adequate real  income to buy y.  
   Classical theorists could not understand how there could be lack of demand  
   for y. Well, there is no lack of demand. But there is lack of means of  
   payment. John cannot pay for y with x, he must pay for y with z, but he does  
   not have z. So he must get money and with it, empower Paul to get z with  
   money. That is, paying with money is a ploy to pay with goods belonging to  
   other people. It has nothing to do with price.  
  
  
   So when Keynes says effective demand, he seems to refer to demand coupled  
   with ability to pay in addition to ability to buy.  In the example, John  
   must convert x into money before he can purchase y. Thus owning x is not  
   effective as demand, but it is demand in the classical sense.  
  
  
   3. Animal spirits of outside animals? The savings-investment equilibrium of  
   course must be present to clear the market in the first dimension, but it  
   has no relevance in the second dimension. The new reader may notice the  
   existence of banks as issuers of (fiat) external money, without being either  
   the  producer or the consumer of real goods. The big bad animal with a  
   wayward spit lives in Lombard Street of good old London. May be the readers  
   group should visit the financial city to see how the bankers are able to  
   increase or decrease the supply of money without any consideration of the  
   volume of actual output or productivity or real profitability prospects.  If  
   the bankers are lending money to stock market speculators, they may be  
   pumping in too much money compared to the stock of real goods. But with a  
   few spectacular failures of borrowers, they bankers may also cut down the  
   supply  of  money  even  if  no decline has occurred in real output or  
   productivity or profitability.  
  
  
   This animal spirit is wholly different from the spirit of the investors in  
   real  output and the savers who save out of real output.  The marginal  
   propensity to consume and the marginal propensity to save should give fair  
   warning that the real people are not as wily the animals as business cycle  
   would require them to be. Are business cycles adequately explained by wild  
   fluctuations in marginal propensity to consume or to save?  
  
  
   The wily ones are in the City. And they are increasing or decreasing the  
   supply of fiat money according to their wily animal spirits.  
  
  
   In short, the failure of the market to clear in the second dimension lies  
   outside the real sector: it is not in the factory floors or in the farm  
   lands;  it is in the banks. This money does not grow out like crops of  
   savings (or savings of real crops?), and surely does not fall from Friedmans  
   endogenous helicopter (or like weeds growing spontaneously or as spontaneous  
   classical veils like on the faces of Afghan women under the Taliban?). This  
   money is created out of thin air and it vanishes into thin air.  Yes, there  
   is that animal, not unlike the Alice in Wonderland capacity of the Cheshire  
   Cat: he may vanish, but his smile or grin may not. He is not real, and yet  
   he has effect, like the ghost.  May be it is a spirit behaving like an  
   animal: the spirit of Wall Street?  
  
  
   May you read Keynes ever so happily.  
  
  
   Mohammad Gani  
  
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2