In article <[log in to unmask]>, Mises Daily
Article <[log in to unmask]> writes
>
>
>Visit the Mises Economics Blog.
>Mises in Defense of Edgeworth
>by Ludwig von Mises
>[Posted on Tuesday, September 20, 2005]
> Introduction by Joseph T. Salerno:
>
> Mises's review of Francis Ysidro Edgeworth's collected papers was published in
>German in 1926. It was translated by JoAnn Rothbard and appears here in English
>for the first time.
>
> Despite its brevity, it is an extremely important document for both Mises
>scholars and Austrian economists generally. For it is in this review that Mises
>clearly reveals his attitude toward the third branch of the marginalist
>revolution, whose two other branches comprised the Austrian school pioneered by
>Carl Menger and Eugen von B�hm-Bawerk and the Lausanne school founded by L�on
>Walras and Vilfredo Pareto.
>
> Scattered throughout Mises's prodigious writings, one encounters numerous
>references to the Lausanne school, whose mathematical methods he argued were
>sterile and misleading in theoretical research in economics. In surprising
>contrast, Mises referred very sparingly to the British branch of marginalism or
>"neoclassicism" which has been associated most closely with the work of Alfred
>Marshall.
>
> There is only one reference to Marshall in Human Action, Mises's 900-page
>treatise on economic theory, and none in Epistemological Problems of Economics,
>his pathbreaking collection of essays on economic methodology.
>
> One could, however, infer something of Mises's view of British neoclassicism
>in an essay critical of Keynes. There he included among a list of Keynes's
>rhetorical "stratagems": "It is assumed that the evolution of economic science
>culminated with Alfred Marshall and ended with him. The findings of modern
>subjective economics are disregarded."
>
> From this statement one might surmise that Mises, first, considered Alfred
>Marshall the leading British economist of the late nineteenth and early
>twentieth centuries and, second, in the hands of the followers of Menger and B�
>hm-Bawerk economic theory had been advanced well beyond the state where it had
>been left in Marshall's work, which still dominated economic thinking in Great
>Britain in the mid-1920s. The reader would be incorrect in the first surmise and
>correct in the second. For in the review below Mises declared, "Edgeworth has
>been the foremost economist in England during the latter part of the 19th
>century and the beginning of the 20th century."
>
> Mises's judgment in this matter is utterly unorthodox and flies in the face of
>the view accepted as a matter of course by practically all post-World War I
>economists including the most prominent specialists in the intellectual
>development of the discipline. It is also just one more indication of Mises's
>fierce independence of thought and his impossibly broad and deep acquaintance
>with the economic literature of all countries and epochs.
>
> Mises unstintingly praised Edgeworth's contributions in advancing economic
>science and serving as a stimulus for the research of younger economists in
>Great Britain. He favorably quoted several statements by Edgeworth - much of
>whose own work employed mathematical techniques - counseling severe restraint in
>the use of mathematics in economics and pointing out the limited results yielded
>by its use. Nevertheless, despite his great respect for Edgeworth's intellect
>and scholarship, Mises leaves no doubt that British neoclassicism had reached a
>dead end long before 1926: "Although Edgeworth in the preface justifies much of
>the work, he must admit that a sizable portion of it is already obsolete. There
>is scarcely any value in the essays on money, and also in the part about the
>work on catallactics."
>
> Thus, to our great benefit, in this review we at last have a forthright
>statement of Mises's attitude toward a major competing school of thought and its
>neglected master theoretician.
>
> ---Joseph T. Salerno, September 21, 2005
>
>Review of F.Y. Edgeworth's Papers Relating to Political Economy, by Ludwig von
>Mises. (London, 1925). Jahrbuch f�r Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft
>(Schmollers Jahrbuch). 49:6(1926)1400-01. (translated by JoAnn B. Rothbard)
>
>F. Edgeworth has been the foremost economist in England during the latter part
>of the 19th century and the beginning of the 20th century. As a teacher at
>Oxford he contributed toward the development of the present type of English
>economics. For many years editor of the Economic Journal, which is still the
>most important and the oldest journal of economics, he had a lasting influence
>on the scientific evolution of his country. His personality was impressed on the
>organ of the Royal Economic Society. In numerous critiques he has taken the
>position of scientific literature to the newer economists and in many
>penetrating essays handled the fundamental problems of our science.
>
>Almost all of his scientific activity has been made public through this
>periodical. Edgeworth had never published an independent book of political
>economy but his essays and critiques well atone for a number of ponderous books.
>One must therefore be grateful for the economic fellowship that has now made
>possible the exhibition of the most important collected works of the venerable
>scholar.
>
>The first volume of this collection contains Edgeworth's contribution to
>catallactics. It is articulated in three parts: value and distribution, monopoly
>theory, and theory of money. The second volume contains a discussion of the
>theory of international trade, then a sketch on theory of taxation, and finally
>a number of essays on mathematical economy. The third volume brings the work to
>a close.
>
>Edgeworth has made use of mathematical methods in his work. However his notions
>of the utility and usefulness of the mathematical method in economics are quite
>restrained. In an abridgement which had been published in a previous collection
>of his, "On the Application of Mathematics to Political Economy", he says:
>"Mathematics is ... useful, though not an indispensable adjunct to economic
>studies; a finish to the training of an economist comparable with a knowledge of
>the classics as part of a general education" (11, pg. 274). This cautious
>evaluation of the usefulness of mathematical procedures in economics one agrees
>with completely without hesitation. However one can better define Edgeworth's
>understanding of the value of mathematics with another remark. Again in one of
>the editions' prefatory notices to one of the essays he says of the transference
>of classroom doctrine into the language of mathematics: "Not much is gained by
>the translation into mathematical language" (11, pg. 4). It is detrimental that
>Edgeworth devotes too much time and toil to this work for he must finally
>acknowledge that it cannot bring any great victories to our science.
>
>Naturally, it is not possible, in framing a review of a work of over 1,200
>difficult pages, to pass on the individuality of 34 individual essays and more
>than 70 critiques. Although Edgeworth in the preface justifies much of the work,
>he must admit that a sizable portion of it is already obsolete. There is
>scarcely any value in the essays on money, and also in the part about the work
>on catallactics. It is justified, however, in that the obsolete essays have been
>used by newer economists.
>
>The historians of theory will have to pay heed to this work. But even those who
>do not read history of theory, but seek the explanation of difficult problems,
>will find much here; at any rate, more than one would expect from a cursory
>perusal. For Edgeworth is initially a critic; he is better able to discover the
>insufficiencies in others and to formulate problems, than to find the solution
>himself.
>
>
>
>The high point of the collection is a lecture which Edgeworth delivered in 1891
>upon assuming his teaching post at Oxford. This essay, titled "The Objects and
>Methods of Political Economy" is in form and content a small masterpiece. And
>while one can scarcely imagine that this bulky, not too readable, and by German
>standards, rather expensive book, will find many readers in Germany, it marks a
>return to the relation of economic research to economic theory:
>"As the producer of wealth will push his investment in the different agents of
>production up to a certain limit which has been called 'margin of
>profitableness'; so, in the manufacture of economic wisdom, each of us should
>expend his little fund of energy, partly on the fixed capital of the deductive
>organon and partly on the materials of historical experience. The margin of
>profitableness in the intellectual as in the external world will differ with the
>personality of individuals. No general rule is available, except that, like the
>cultivated Athenian, we should eschew the invidious disparagement of each
>other's pursuits."
>
>________________________________
>
>Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973) was dean of the Austrian School. Comment on the
>blog.
>
Chris R. Tame
|