Colander, David wrote:
>James wonders why historians of thought who are also textbook writers (I
>wonder who he has in mind) have not put this "theoretical fraud" to
>rest. The issues are complicated. First, IS/LM, while it has problems is
>not a theoretical fraud, and its history and derivation has been
>extensively studied.
>
All the textbook writers out there who also are historians of economic
thought know themselves without my naming them. Surely, David is one.
I have a copy of his 2002 /Macroeconomics/ text (with Edward Gamber),
but I don't use it. For example, in chapter 9, under "Fiscal Policy"
they talk about increased government expenditure shifting the IS curve
to the right and raising total output (income). Now, if David had
attempted to answer the questions I posed yesterday about the legitimacy
of shifting the IS curve when government spending rises, he would have
appreciated my calling that exercise at "theoretical fraud." It is true
that IS-LM model's "history and derivation (sic) has been extensively
studied." But that shouldn't stop anyone from pointing out what's still
wrong with the model, does it? (I write about the "Persistent problems
with the IS-LM model" in my /Classical Macroeconomics/ (2003, pp.
185-90).
David continues:
>Why does IS/LM persist? I've written about this in "The Strange
>Persistence of IS/LM" in HOPE which is reprinted in my collection of
>essays "The Stories Economists Tell". Essentially, my argument is that
>it serves as a graph to hang discussions of policy on, and that's what
>the focus is in the undergraduate macro theory course.
>
This is not a saving argument for continuing with the theoretical
fraud. If the IS curve legitimately can not shift right when government
spending increases, when investment spending increases, or when consumer
spending increases (and the so-called AD is stuck in place), of what use
is the model as a device "to hang discussions of policy on"? Frankly, I
don't see it.
Finally, David writes:
>In my texts I have tried to make clear what the issues are, but when I
>have developed them in full--reviewers said the presentations became too
>complicated for students. They are not interested in theory--just
>policy. I think it is important to see textbooks for what they are
>pedagogical devices to convey ideas to students. They often differ from
>the way economists who are working in the subject see the issues.
With all due respect, I don't think it is possible to rescue the IS-LM
model from its fundamental flaws. Trying too hard to achieve that feat
would legitimately prompt such reactions from book reviewers. As
Leijonhufvud (1981, 151) has noted the IS-LM model is "more a hindrance
than help in coming to grips" with the substantive issues between Keynes
and the classics that Hicks was trying to sort out. Robert Barro (1983,
vi) also acutely observes that the model "leaves students with a poor
understanding of how the economy works." Barro (2008, viii) also
writes: "Undergraduate macro textbooks and courses seem frequently to
compromise good economics for presentations that are breezy, closely
linked to arguments found in the popular press, and not very
intellectually challenging. But sacrificing solid economics to capture
student interest is not necessary --- sound theory can be clearly
written with vivid examples to reinforce it." So why create a
pedagogical device which mainly solidifies myths and confusions in
students' minds. Remember that it is these students who would one day
become "the ... economists ... working in the subject." Why not give
them the correct tools from the start?
Thus, if one wants to explain the price level, one could adapt Alfred
Marshall's (1923) "Diagrammatic Note on a Metallic Currency,"
substituting paper currency for the metal to do that rather than the
AS-AD diagram derived from some theoretical myths (see pp. 68-75of my
/Classical Macroeconomics/.). To repeat, I can understand current
macroeconomists who have little acquaintance with the history of
economic thought or who think doing the history of economic thought
constitutes wasteful "detours" from the macroeconomics they want to
teach (Robert Frank and Ben Bernanke, 2002, xii) not recognizing the
errors of the IS-LM and AS-AD models. It baffles me when those doing
the history of economic thought fail to help bury the mess.
James Ahiakpor
|