SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Date:
Fri May 12 08:48:18 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (296 lines)
------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------  
Classic Reviews in Economic History  
  
Thomas C. Smith, _The Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan_. Stanford:   
Stanford University Press, 1959. xi + 250 pp.  
  
Review Essay by Osamu Saito, Institute of Economic Research,   
Hitotsubashi University.  
  
  
                A Peasant Economy and the Growth of the Market  
  
In the 1950s, when the late Professor Thomas Smith wrote this book,   
peasant farming was portrayed as a mode of production and livelihood   
incompatible with the market economy. Japan before Meiji was regarded   
as a typical example of such peasant economies. As Smith notes in the   
opening sentence of the book, this was to some extent true because   
"In the course of its long history, Japanese agriculture has in some   
respects changed remarkably little": farming was a family enterprise,   
holdings tiny and fragmented, and cultivation methods simple -- all   
features of a typical peasant society. Of course, there were some   
changes but they were never as dramatic as the agrarian changes the   
West experienced, so that for many scholars "it is tempting to   
dismiss as unimportant such changes as in fact have taken place."   
Against this historiographical background, Smith argues in the book   
that the changes that actually took place in Japanese history,   
especially in the Tokugawa period (1603-1868), were in fact of great   
importance. His argument is that "their central feature was a shift   
from cooperative to individual farming" and that "if one of its   
causes may be singled out as especially important, it must be the   
_growth of the market_" (pp. ix-x; emphasis added).  
  
The book is about these changes and, based largely on a body of   
evidence uncovered by Japanese historians, traces their social and   
economic consequences. It begins with a model of the traditional   
village society in the seventeenth century, which is set out in Part   
I. At the core of village society, according to that model, was a   
large landholder's domestic group. It was composed of three   
concentric circles with the inner one being the family of the holder,   
the main household. The second circle consisted of a group of   
relatives outside the direct line of descent, and the third circle of   
hereditary servants and similar subordinate persons who were related   
to the holder by neither blood nor marriage but were nonetheless   
registered as part of his family group. In every village such large   
holder households were not many; only a few took this form of   
"extended family." Other villagers were all small holders whose   
family form was, according to Smith, in most cases "nuclear"; and   
they were in all likelihood households created by partitioning. Since   
the partition of family land, even when practiced, was never made on   
an equal footing, those "new" groups of branch-family households were   
bound to be small holders who had to rely on resources provided by   
the main household as well as the village itself. Thus the structure   
of the traditional village was both cooperative and hierarchical,   
with "clusters of interdependent interests that clung together with   
great force and were broken up only when competitive inducements of   
trade began, much later, to dissolve the internal ties" (p. 54).  
  
Such "competitive inducements" came from market growth in the   
countryside, which, it is suggested, was concomitant with urban   
growth. Thus, Smith begins Part II with a survey of the extent of   
commercial farming (cultivation of cotton, indigo, mulberries,   
oilseeds, tobacco, and other cash crops) and farm family   
by-employment (spinning, reeling, weaving, straw plaiting, etc.),   
both of which are supposed to have spread in the rural provinces   
during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. Then in the   
subsequent chapters Smith traces the consequent changes: how   
agricultural technology changed, how labor was transformed, how   
wealthy landlords emerged within the village society, and how the   
traditional ties between households dissolved. The underlying   
tendency in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries was for some   
branch families and hereditary servants to become separate from the   
main household. They formed their own households. Their landholding   
was sometimes too small to feed themselves on the farm, but thanks to   
the expanding market economy, they were in all likelihood able to   
find either by-employment opportunities or wage jobs, or both, as   
former labor service was increasingly replaced by live-in servants on   
yearly contract, who were eventually substituted by workers employed   
by the day. Sometimes, especially in crisis years, they had to borrow   
money from large holders in the village with a parcel of land placed   
in pawn, which in many cases ended up with the loss of its holding   
right: they became tenants of the large holders. The latter half of   
the Tokugawa period saw their numbers increasing, but at the same   
time it is not unlikely that increased tenancy in turn allowed them   
to stay on the land. With these significant, if not revolutionary,   
tendencies established, Smith devotes the final chapter to relating   
them to the making of modern Japan, placing particular emphasis on   
what commercial farming and expanding labor markets taught peasants   
in relation to the forthcoming age of the factory.  
  
The book's major points, such as the supposition that the weight of   
non-agricultural income in the rural economy had become substantial   
by the early nineteenth century, have subsequently been confirmed by   
his own and other historians' works (Smith 1969/88, Nishikawa 1987,   
Shimbo and Saito 2004). From an early twenty-first century vantage   
point, however, it is not surprising that the progress of research   
since then has made some of the other propositions no longer tenable.   
One such example is his description of a shift from "extended" to   
"nuclear" family. Each of the cooperative groups in   
seventeenth-century documents that he regarded as one large and   
complex family household was probably nothing but an estate   
organization accommodating several separate domestic groups together,   
most of which were family households in a much simpler form and   
possessed their own hearth and living space. As a unit of production,   
however, the structure of the seventeenth-century estate organization   
may have been not much different from what he described in the book:   
it was hierarchical and there were extra-economic ties between those   
households. On the other hand, the family form that he considered   
"nuclear" should now be taken to mean "stem family," since by the   
term "nuclear" Smith meant a small family that had no lateral   
extension but tended to extend vertically. As far as the family   
system is concerned, therefore, there seems to have been little   
change throughout the Tokugawa period. What actually changed was the   
way in which farming was organized and its tasks carried out, which   
was _not_ associated with a transformation in the system of family   
formation. Another point I have to make concerns the extent of   
urbanization and the role given to it as an engine of market growth.   
In the chapter on "The Growth of the Market," Smith noted that "in   
the two centuries after 1600, urban population grew with astonishing   
speed" (p. 67). Probably it did as far as the seventeenth century is   
concerned, but we now know, from Smith's own research work published   
later, that urban population did not grow in the one and a half   
centuries after 1700: Edo, Osaka and some of the castle towns even   
recorded a population decline. Market-led output growth -- "Smithian   
growth" in recent terminology (named after Adam Smith) -- that took   
place in the latter half of the Tokugawa period should now be   
considered "rural-centered" (Smith 1973/88; see also Shimbo and Saito   
2004).  
  
Such necessary revisions notwithstanding, _The Agrarian Origins of   
Modern Japan_ remains a landmark achievement in Tokugawa economic   
history. It is not just because the book is still very informative   
and makes lucid reading, but chiefly because what Smith delineated   
with respect to "what changed" and "what remained unchanged" is   
largely accurate. Given the intellectual milieu of the 1950s and the   
60s, however, this publication may have been considered a book about   
"what changed" only -- a work fitting very nicely in the framework of   
modernization theses such as the rise of individualism and the   
transition from status to contract, since the "growth of the market,"   
the guiding concept of the book, has long been regarded as an   
important component of the modernization process.  
  
However, Smith makes several important points that do not necessarily   
fit with the modernization scenarios. First, he makes it clear that   
Tokugawa Japan's path of agricultural progress was distinctly   
different from the Western one, suggesting that they would never   
converge on a single model. As he describes in the chapter on   
"Agricultural Technology," farm output rose with the expansion of   
commercial farming, which was closely associated with the more   
intensive use of fertilizers, widening plant varieties, proliferation   
of farming tools, and the extension of irrigation. The irrigation   
work, i.e. construction of dikes, ponds, ditches, devices for lifting   
water into paddy fields and for other purposes, required a   
substantial amount of capital, much of which was provided by   
overlords and wealthy merchants. At the same time, however, the   
construction work itself required a substantial input of labor. And   
all the other improvements in farming methods were also labor   
intensive. Some individual innovations may have reduced labor   
requirements per unit of cultivated land, but the overall effect was   
to intensify the use of labor. All this made farming even more labor   
intensive and the unit of farming even smaller, the characteristics   
that remained unchanged throughout the period from Tokugawa to Meiji.   
To put it differently, "the character of agrarian change [in Tokugawa   
and Meiji Japan] ... was determined as much by what did _not_ change   
about farming as by what did" (p. 208; see also Ishikawa 1978,   
Francks 1983).  
  
Secondly, while Smith examines in detail the rise of landlord-tenant   
relations and its accompanying phenomenon of increasing   
differentiation of landholdings within the agrarian society, and also   
the processes of hereditary subordinates evolving into servants for   
yearly wages and of service agreements becoming from long-term to   
short-term contracts, thus describing a long-run transition to wage   
labor, he never speaks of the emergence of a wage earning class of   
landless agricultural labors. This may be interpreted as suggesting   
that those tendencies, together with the above-mentioned move towards   
the intensification in farming and the spread of non-agricultural   
by-employments in the rural districts, resulted in keeping the   
peasantry from disintegrating itself (Saito 1986).  
  
Thirdly, therefore, all this "kept the agricultural population a   
relatively homogeneous class of small peasant farmers despite the   
presence of landlords and obvious differences in wealth; [and] it   
preserved the organic unity of the village community despite the   
growth of a nonfarming population within it" (p. 107). In other   
words, the coming of commercial farming and the associated growth of   
labor markets in the Tokugawa period did not signal the end of a   
peasant economy. Rather, in the Japanese past peasant farming evolved   
towards more uniformity as the market grew.  
  
Thus, this 1959 book suggested that the Tokugawa peasant household,   
as an integral unit of production and reproduction, had a modus   
operandi distinctly different from those found for other early modern   
agricultural populations, and also that it emerged in the process of   
interactions with the growth of the market. Smith addressed this   
research question later when he worked on demography and on the   
history of time discipline (Smith 1977, 1986/88). In the first, he   
demonstrated how the Tokugawa peasant families tried, with a dim idea   
of family planning, to adjust their size and composition to   
alternating life-cycle stages and also changing economic   
circumstances, and in the second, how they developed a stringent   
sense of time discipline within the household in order to cope with   
the increased intensity of labor in farming and by-employment   
activities and, hence, an increased need for planning over the whole   
farming year. This latter point implies that Meiji Japanese workers   
did not need to be taught time discipline in the factory, which   
strongly suggests that there was _continuity_ from Tokugawa to Meiji.   
In the former demographic study, Smith made a strong argument that   
Tokugawa peasants adjusted their family size and composition by means   
of sex selective infanticide. This provoked a debate, but as I have   
commented elsewhere (Saito 1989), the gist of his entire argument was   
that the Tokugawa peasant family household tried hard to balance its   
numbers with farm size and to secure the right composition in the   
family workforce, for which purpose infanticide was only one of the   
options accessible to the family. There were some other means of   
demographic adjustments such as abortion and the timing of   
marriage-out of non-inheriting children, as well as economic ones   
such as sending children, both male and female, into service in the   
village and in cities and towns, or getting them to take up an   
industrial by-employment at home. Those economic opportunities   
increased with the growth of the market, and with changes that   
accelerated after the Meiji reforms. This consideration, therefore,   
points to another element of _continuity_ from the early modern to   
the modern period, the theme already explicit in the writing of _The   
Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan_.  
  
Smith noted, retrospectively in the preface to a collection of essays   
he had published since the 1950s, that while writing on "how Japan   
became a modern society ... with a generalized notion drawn from   
Western history of how much transformations occur," he had "paid   
particular attention to factors that contributed to making modern   
Japanese society similar to but _profoundly different_ from Western   
counterparts" (Smith 1988, p. 1; emphasis added). As such, therefore,   
his work collectively made a pioneering contribution to the on-going   
debates in global economic history.  
  
References:  
  
Francks, P. (1983), _Technology and Agricultural Development in   
Pre-war Japan_, New Haven: Yale University Press.  
  
Ishikawa, S. (1978), _Labour Absorption in Asian Agriculture: An   
Issues Paper_, Bangkok: Asian Regional Programme for Employment   
Promotion of the International Labour Office; reprinted in S.   
Ishikawa (1981), _Essays on Technology, Employment and Institutions   
in Economic Development_, Tokyo: Kinokuniya, 1-149.  
  
Nishikawa, S. (1987), "The Economy of Ch�sh� on the Eve of   
Industrialization," _Economics Studies Quarterly_ 38 (December),   
323-37.  
  
Saito, O. (1986), "The Rural Economy: Commercial Agriculture,   
By-employment and Wage Work," in M.B. Jansen and G. Rozman, eds.,   
_Japan in Transition: From Tokugawa to Meiji_, Princeton: Princeton   
University Press, 400-420.  
  
Saito, O. (1989), "Bringing the Covert Structure of the Past to   
Light: Review Article of T.C. Smith, _Native Sources of Japanese   
Industrialization, 1750-1920_," _Journal of Economic History_ 49   
(December), 992-999.  
  
Shimbo, H. and O. Saito (2004), "The Economy on the Eve of   
Industrialization," in A. Hayami, O. Saito and R.P. Toby, eds., _The   
Economic History of Japan, 1600-1990_. I: _Emergence of Economic   
Society in Japan, 1600-1859_, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 337-68.  
  
Smith, T.C. (1969), "Farm Family By-employments in Preindustrial   
Japan," _Journal of Economic History_ 29 (December), 687-715;   
reprinted in Smith (1988), 71-102.  
  
Smith, T.C. (1973), "Pre-modern Economic Growth: Japan and the West,"   
_Past and Present_ 60 (August), 127-160; reprinted in Smith (1988),   
15-49.  
  
Smith, T.C. (1977), _Nakahara: Family Farming and Population in a   
Japanese Village, 1717-1830_, Stanford: Stanford University Press.  
  
Smith, T.C. (1986), "Peasant Time and Factory Time in Japan," _Past   
and Present_ 111 (May), 165-197; reprinted in Smith (1988), 199-235.  
  
Smith, T.C. (1988), _Native Sources of Japanese Industrialization,   
1750-1920_, Berkeley: University of California Press.  
  
  
Copyright (c) 2006 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be   
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to   
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the   
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).   
Published by EH.Net (May 2006). All EH.Net reviews are archived at   
http://www.eh.net/BookReview.  
  
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW  --------------  
EH.Net-Review mailing list  
[log in to unmask]  
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review  
  

ATOM RSS1 RSS2