SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:46 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (289 lines)
------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW -------------- 
Published by EH.NET (February 2005) 
 
D. P. O'Brien, _The Classical Economists Revisited_. Princeton, NJ:  
Princeton University Press, 2004. xviii + 423 pp. $39,95 (cloth),  
ISBN: 0-691-11939-2. 
 
Reviewed for EH.NET by Elisabeth Allgoewer, Institut f=FCr  
Wirtschaftssysteme, Wirtschafts- und Theoriegeschichte, University of  
Hamburg. 
 
 
With _The Classical Economists Revisited_, Denis O'Brien, emeritus at  
the University of Durham, has provided a revised edition of his _The  
Classical Economists_ published in 1975 by Clarendon Press. The new  
edition is very much welcome as it will make this -- in itself  
"classic" -- text available to new generations of students and  
scholars. 
 
While the structure of the original work remains unchanged, a new  
(final) chapter 11 "Classical Economics: A Retrospect" has been  
added. Comparing individual chapters with the original, chapter 7 on  
"International Trade" has received most of the changes. A new (short)  
section on "Customs Unions" has been added. The newly created  
subsections mostly cover material also contained in the original  
version, extended, however, through additional graphical expositions.  
To chapter 9 on "Classical Public Finance" an appendix on "Net  
Present Value Taxation" has been added. Furthermore, additional  
graphical expositions (e.g. figures 6.1 and 6.2) and formal  
presentations (e.g. on the wages fund theory) have been included.  
Most importantly, the annotated bibliographies at the end of each  
chapter have been updated. As in the first edition, the "Further  
Reading" is invaluable to students trying to find their way into the  
field. Last but not least, the new edition makes the book even more  
accessible for reference. The index is considerably more detailed,  
additional keywords and further names have been included. 
 
In the "Introduction" O'Brien characterizes the approach taken in the  
book "to convey a picture of the broad range of Classical literature"  
rather than to focus on "key individuals" (xvi). Accordingly, the  
material is organized around themes. The first three chapters provide  
a general introduction. Chapter one on "The Classical Economic Stage"  
gives an overview of the authors whose contributions are discussed in  
the core chapters and their educational and professional backgrounds.  
Noteworthy is O'Brien's discussion of the importance of institutions,  
journals, and newspapers which framed the exchange of ideas. This  
allows him to discuss the extent to which their contributions can be  
seen as emerging from "a scientific community." 
 
Chapter 2 on "The Roots of Classical Economics" surveys intellectual  
influences from philosophy and pre-classical economic writings and  
inspiration taken from historical developments such as population  
growth or industrialization. In two admirably concise sections Adam  
Smith's system and David Ricardo's corn model are presented,  
highlighting these contributions as providing a starting point or  
point of reference for "later" Classical economists. Their  
contributions are characterized in some detail for John Stuart Mill  
and in shorter paragraphs on Robert Torrens, Nassau Senior, John  
Ramsay McCulloch, Thomas Robert Malthus and Thomas Tooke. 
 
The last of the introductory chapters is on "The Characteristics and  
Preconceptions of Classical Economics." It underlines the Classical  
focus on dynamics and shows how issues of allocation arise in the  
context of the concern with growth. The occupation with population is  
traced back to Hume in the following section which continues with a  
succinct discussion of Malthus's _Essay on Population_ and its  
reception by Classical economists. The ensuing section on method is  
similarly outstanding by providing a dense and accessible overview  
without simplifying the issues at hand. 
 
Chapter 4 opens the more detailed discussion of Classical analysis to  
be pursued in the following chapters. The survey of "Classical Value  
Theory" is subdivided into four sections. Smith's rejection of  
subjective value theory and his development of a cost-of-production  
theory are motivated by his interest in the analysis of macroeconomic  
distribution. The analysis of market vs. long-run equilibria is  
discussed and Smith's concern with labor as a measure of welfare.  
Ricardo's contribution to the labor theory of value is the next  
topic, followed by a discussion of "Cost-of-Production Theories of  
Value after Ricardo." The chapter is complemented by a presentation  
of the contributions of individual authors to subjective value theory  
in the Classical era substantiating O'Brien's claim that there was a  
noteworthy stream of pre-neoclassical subjective-value arguments. 
 
The analysis of "The Classical Theory of Distribution" in chapter 5  
treats wages, profits and rents separately before turning to  
"Relative Shares." In the section on wages, the analysis of the  
problems of the wage fund theories deserves mentioning. The  
discussion of profits is another example of O'Brien's mastery of  
exposition when it comes to intricate subject matters. Graphical  
analysis and Ricardo's numerical examples are used to contrast  
Smith's and Ricardo's contributions on relative shares. 
 
Chapter 6 on "Classical Monetary Theory" starts with a somewhat short  
overview of the historical background. However, this would be my only  
criticism of an otherwise superb discussion of a topic which has  
received much attention. A fairly unanimous Classical consensus on  
"The Nature of Money" focusing on money as a means of exchange based  
on a monometallic standard and leading to a narrow definition of  
money is developed. Nonetheless, O'Brien convincingly argues that  
Classical economists appreciated the function of banking. "The Basic  
Theory" founded on the quantity theory of money and the  
price-specie-flow mechanism are developed and linked to the analysis  
of the international distribution of precious metals. On this  
background the arguments brought forward in the Bullionist  
controversy and the debates between Currency and Banking Schools are  
discussed in detail. Dealing with Say's law of markets in the next  
section complements the analysis in the conventional way. In  
contrast, the section on "Inflation" covers material usually given  
little attention. O'Brien underlines the Classical awareness of real  
effects of changes in the money supply, traces the analysis back to  
Hume and shows how these arguments were used to warn of deflation  
rather than to advocate inflation. 
 
Chapter 7 covers "International Trade." The discussion of Smith's  
contribution is followed by a detailed exposition of the analysis of  
comparative advantage. O'Brien sets off the Classical argument from a  
Heckscher-Ohlin type analysis, a sideline which I find welcome in  
countering the stripped-down presentations of the Classical arguments  
contained in many textbooks on trade. The following sections cover  
Classical contributions on the determination of terms of trade  
supported by graphical exposition. Free trade is further examined  
under the heading "Trade Policy," where widely accepted exceptions to  
the principle are expounded and the case for unilateral free trade is  
discussed. The analysis of "Customs Unions" and "The Transfer  
Problem" are illustrations of O'Brien's claim that much of  
neoclassical trade theory emerged straight from classical principles.  
However, O'Brien emphasizes that Classical authors posed the issues  
in the context of growth whereas neoclassical analysis focused on  
static analysis leaving much of the dynamic aspects to be  
"rediscovered" in recent decades. 
 
Chapter 8 on "The Classical Theory of Growth and Development" opens  
with Smith's growth theory, a section which repeats some of the  
material already covered in chapter 2. The following section surveys  
"The Classical Vision of Growth after Smith" focusing on Malthus,  
McCulloch and J.S. Mill, thus avoiding similar repetitions of  
Ricardo's contribution. The Classical debates on the effects of  
machinery and the possibility of gluts are covered in the next  
section. Finally, the distinction between productive and unproductive  
labor is discussed. 
 
Chapter 9 on "Classical Public Finance" takes up an often neglected  
subject. Smith's general principles of taxation serve as the starting  
point. A thorough discussion of the distinction between direct and  
indirect taxation and Classical economist's evaluation of both types  
of taxes follows. According to Classical insights, national debt, a  
topical issue in the Classical era as O'Brien shows, presents a  
burden on the future. Ricardo's and Malthus's arguments are presented  
as exceptions to this broad consensus, although on different grounds.  
Ricardo's case is discussed in detail and confronted with the modern  
version of Ricardian equivalence. 
 
"The Policy Prescriptions of Classical Economists" are surveyed in  
chapter 10 which starts with a discussion of "The Legitimate Role of  
Government" aiming at the refutation of the "caricature of Classical  
economists as wild-eyed laissez-faire dogmatists" (327). Instead,  
O'Brien argues, the Classical writers were the earliest "fully to  
appreciate the allocative mechanism of the market." At the same time  
they were "clear that it could only operate within a framework of  
restrictions" (328). The following sections cover aspects of the  
debates on domestic policy issues: the Factory Acts, the effects of  
mechanization, the Poor Laws, public provision of education and trade  
unions. Classical contributions to policy controversies beyond the  
domestic sphere are taken up in the sections on "Policy for Ireland"  
and "Colonies and Colonial Policy." 
 
The final chapter entitled "Classical Economics: A Retrospect" aims  
at an overall evaluation. It highlights arguments developed in the  
core chapters, most of which have already been mentioned. O'Brien  
again underlines his case for Classical economics as a body of  
thought developed by a number of contributors rather than by a few  
outstanding thinkers. His emphasis on the dominance of issues of  
dynamic analysis is repeated. The longevity of the Classical  
contributions to monetary theory, monetary policy analysis and  
international macroeconomics is reconfirmed. The concern with  
pressing problems in the Classical literature on public finance is  
contrasted with much less applicable twentieth-century contributions  
in the field. Last but not least, the policy orientation of Classical  
economics is emphasized, a characteristic certainly not accentuated  
in many textbook treatments focusing on theoretical contributions. 
 
The praise that _The Classical Economists_ received in the reviews of  
the 1975 edition pertains to the revised version. Even though much  
has been published since on the subject matter, none of the many  
monographs and textbooks "can hope to compete with the comprehensive  
range, the firm grasp of detail and the lucid expository style of  
Professor O'Brien's work" as Marc Blaug put it in his review of 1976.  
Andrew Skinner stated in 1976 that the book "should appeal to  
students of economics ... and especially to those who do not have an  
extensive knowledge of the classical period -- an audience which the  
author has constantly in mind." His verdict, that when measured  
against O'Brien's aims, the book "is not markedly unconventional" can  
also be extended to the revised edition. I would, however, add that  
given the stated intention of providing an introduction to the broad  
literature "by" Classical economists and "on" Classical economics, a  
conventional design does serve this purpose best -- especially if it  
is so masterfully executed as in this case. 
 
I particularly enjoyed reading the three introductory chapters which  
provide the framework to the more detailed discussions following in  
the thematic chapters on theory and policy issues. As I tried to show  
above, the chapter on monetary policy is outstanding. The chapters on  
trade and public finance represent areas covered in passing in  
comparable monographs. Finally, the chapter on policy draws together  
a wide range of material which allows O'Brien to circumscribe a  
"Classical approach" to economic policy issues. This does not imply  
the uncovering of straight-forward common principles. Rather, it  
assembles evidence against the frequent allegation of randomness in  
Classical policy advice. Finally, I find it worth emphasizing that  
although Smith, Ricardo, and J.S. Mill clearly receive most of the  
coverage, O'Brien succeeds in presenting Classical economics as  
"essentially a communal effort" (356). The profiles of many of the  
less known figures emerge clearly. 
 
There is one count on which I was disappointed with the revised  
edition. Given the outpouring of publications since the first  
edition, I had hoped to find an explicit discussion of some of the  
more fervent debates concerning the interpretation of Classical  
economics. O'Brien briefly mentions the issue in the introduction  
(xv) just to refer the reader to the controversial literature which  
he lists in three large notes. O'Brien's mastery in presenting  
complicated matters in a form accessible to students, his skill in  
clarifying contentious issues in the historical sources and his  
ability to do justice to authors with opposing views would make him  
an ideal authority to present these "variant readings" (362, n.1) in  
an even-handed account. 
 
Finally, O'Brien's occasional references to a Keynesian mainstream  
survived the revision. To a younger generation of economists they  
must seem anachronistic. A similar point can be made about the  
direction of the argument in the section on economic policy. The text  
explicitly disputes a perception of Classical economists as overly  
laissez-faire. However, in between the lines a further case seems to  
be developed criticizing an over-optimistic belief in the  
effectiveness of government intervention. This belief might have been  
widespread at the time when the book was originally written but is no  
longer today, especially not in economics departments. In short, in  
view of younger readers these implicit arguments seem to reduce some  
of the potential of the chapter. I find many students who attend  
history of thought classes to be disappointed by the little modern  
economic theory seems to offer on economic policy issues. They  
dislike the "narrow technical focus of modern literature" (362) and  
the aloofness of its policy conclusions. However, many of them  
subscribe to a basically liberal outlook also contained in Classical  
economics. On this background Classical economists developed -- if  
controversial -- positions on pressing policy issues which go beyond  
the demand for reduced government intervention so popular today. 
 
Notwithstanding these minor points of criticism _The Classical  
Economists Revisited_ is an asset to any university or private  
library. Even though O'Brien designed the book "to be read as a  
continuous text" (xv), I would highly recommend it to students  
wishing to work on individual aspects of Classical economics. The  
chapters provide concise introductions to issues and topics, the  
bibliographies lead the way to the secondary literature and stress  
over and again the importance of reading the original texts.  
O'Brien's book is a proof as to how enlightening the Classical  
literature is and to how fascinating it becomes. 
 
References: 
 
D.P. O'Brien, _The Classical Economists_ (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975). 
 
Reviewed by Andrew S. Skinner, _The Economic Journal_, Vol. 86, No.  
342 (Jun,. 1976), 373-75. 
 
Reviewed by Mark Blaug, _Economica_, New Series, Vol. 43, No. 171  
(Aug., 1976), 325-6. 
 
 
Elisabeth Allgoewer is Professor of Economics at the University of  
Hamburg. She is currently working on aspects of the reception of  
classical economic thought by German-language authors. 
 
Copyright (c) 2005 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be  
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to  
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the  
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).  
Published by EH.Net (February 2005). All EH.Net reviews are archived  
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview. 
 
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW  -------------- 
EH.Net-Review mailing list 
[log in to unmask] 
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review 
 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2