SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Date:
Fri Oct 20 12:26:49 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (166 lines)
------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------  
Published by EH.NET (October 2006)  
  
Young-Iob Chung, _Korea Under Siege, 1876-1945: Capital Formation and   
Economic Transformation_. New York: Oxford University Press, 2006. xv   
+ 390 pp. $74 (cloth), ISBN: 0-19-517830-0.  
  
Reviewed for EH.NET by Myung Soo Cha, School of Economics and   
Finance, Yeungnam University.  
  
  
_Korea Under Siege, 1876-1945_ claims that Japanese imperialism   
triggered an industrial revolution in Korea, highlighting capital   
accumulation as a key force driving the transition. Following a brief   
introduction, Young-Iob Chung, Professor Emeritus of Economics at   
Eastern Michigan University, begins by describing poverty persisting   
in traditional Korea (Chapter 2). Japan forced dynastic Korea to be   
open to international trade in 1876, allowing modern technologies to   
flow into the country, but living standards hardly improved before   
the beginning of Japanese rule in 1905 (Chapter 3). Modern economic   
growth in Korea required institutional reforms stimulating saving and   
education, which included legalization of property rights and   
modernization of pubic finance and the monetary system as implemented   
during the first decade of the colonial rule (Chapter 4). The next   
three chapters take a closer look at investment: Chapter 5 estimates   
sectoral investment; Chapter 6 explains measures taken to encourage   
investment and identifies sources of funds for different types of   
financial institutions; and Chapter 7 calculates how much of the   
investment was financed by domestic (or foreign) savings and by   
private (or public) savings. The capital accumulation resulted in per   
capita output rising 1.2% per year and primary sector output as a   
share of GDP contracted from around 90% to less than 50% during the   
colonial period (Chapter 8). Beneficiaries of the industrial   
revolution included Japanese landlords, entrepreneurs and skilled   
workers, while living standards enjoyed by Korean peasants and   
unskilled workers hardly improved (Chapter 9). Chapter 10 concludes   
by claiming that in terms of economic development the colonial rule   
was a "blessings in disguise" bestowed on Koreans by Japanese   
taxpayers.  
  
The tale of Japanese colonialism rescuing Korea from a Malthusian   
trap sounds not only plausible (if not politically correct in Korea),   
but also familiar. What makes this volume unique is its focus on   
capital accumulation. Unfortunately, the author does not make any   
attempt to validate this important claim, confining himself to   
presenting aggregate input and output growth estimates. Had he used   
these numbers to do growth accounting, the outcome would have been   
quite misleading, because they are at best ballpark figures.  
  
First, Chung conjectures that the Korean aggregate output grew 3% per   
year under Japanese rule, taking an average of two very different   
estimates: the growth rate of output from primary and secondary   
sectors as estimated by Suh (1978) and the aggregate output growth   
rate taken from an obscure conference paper. Chung apparently is   
unaware of Mizoguchi and Umemura (1988), the outcome of the first   
serious effort to estimate the national accounts of colonial Korea,   
which portrays the colony as growing considerably faster than Chung's   
estimate - i.e., 4% per year. A more recent and refined calculation   
by researchers at the Naksungdae Institute of Economic Research (full   
details published in Korean as Kim (2006) and English summary   
included in Cha and Kim (2006)) produced a somewhat slower growth   
rate, 3.7% per year.  
  
Second, Chung offers a population growth estimate - 1.8% from 1904-43   
- calculated from the number of residents as published in the   
Statistical Yearbook of the Colonial Government. This is an   
overestimate, because the first census taken in 1925 revealed that   
the pre-1925 enumeration left out a considerable number of Koreans.   
Projecting backwards the downward trend in mortality found in census   
results, Ishi (1972) argued that population expanded significantly   
more slowly than Chung believes - 1.4% per year from 1906-44. This,   
in combination with the recent output growth estimates, implies per   
capita output growing twice as fast as Chung claims.  
  
Finally, drawing on paid-in capital as published in firms' financial   
statements and capital spending as recorded in public accounts, Chung   
estimates that investment from 1905-38 amounted to 6.4 billion yen.   
This figure is about twice as large as the sum of investment   
(estimated as a spending item in the national accounts of colonial   
Korea) from 1911-38. Young (1995: 651) observed similar inconsistency   
between investment in the South Korean national accounts and capital   
stock in the South Korean national wealth surveys, the latter being   
the sum of the value of asset ownership as declared by individual   
firms. Then he chose to use the investment figures in the national   
expenditure accounts, the reason being that they are at least   
constrained by the production accounts, while there is no way of   
checking the reliability of numbers offered by firms.  
  
Chung's assessment of the trends in colonial living standards sounds   
unduly pessimistic as a result of not paying enough attention to the   
mortality decline occurring under Japanese rule. Incomes earned by   
unskilled workers and tenant farmers did fail to rise as a matter of   
trend, which together with rising life expectancy implies improving   
living standards. The mortality decline also should have been   
highlighted in Chapter 4 as an important aspect of human capital   
accumulation, in addition to the spread of modern education. Chung   
presents falling per capita food availability as another piece of   
evidence proving that the benefits of economic growth failed to   
trickle down to a large majority of Koreans. The downward trend may   
well be a figment of the overestimated population growth, however. A   
recent estimate of pre-1925 population (based on demographic   
information from genealogies) suggests a growth rate even slower than   
Ishi (1972) - 1.3% per year - removing the negative time trend in per   
capita food availability (Cha (2006)).  
  
Justly portraying the colonial government as bringing about modern   
economic growth in Korea through institutional modernization, Chung   
at the same time launches unjustified critiques of some of its policy   
measures. Most primary prices fell in the late 1920s and early 1930s   
all over the world, which makes it implausible to attribute falling   
rice prices in Korea to policy interventions to stimulate rice   
production. The external shock (known as the interwar agricultural   
depression) appeared to cause a number of irrigation associations to   
go bankrupt. While Chung explains the debacle in terms of the   
colonial government enforcing wasteful investment in irrigation,   
investigations using financial records of individual irrigation   
associations found no evidence to support the assertion (Chang, et al   
(1992)).  
  
References:  
  
Cha, Myung Soo. 2006. "Kyo�ngje so�ngjang, kujopyo�nhwa, sodu�k   
punbae," in Nak Nyeon Kim. ed. _Han'guk u�i kyo�ngje so�ngjang   
1910-1945_. Seoul: Seoul National University Press.  
  
Cha, Myung Soo and Nak Nyeon Kim. 2006. "Korea's First Industrial   
Revolution," Naksungdae Institute of Economic Research Working Paper   
no. 2006-3.  
  
Chang, S. Matsumoto, T. Miyajima, H. and Rhee, Y. eds. 1992. _Ku�ndae   
choso�n suri chohap yo�n'gu_ Seoul: Ilchogak.  
  
Ishi,Yoshikuni. 1972. _Kankoku no jink� no bunseki_. Tokyo: Keis� shob�.  
  
Kim, Nak Nyeon. ed. 2006. _Han'guk u�i kyo�ngje so�ngjang 1910-1945_.   
Seoul: Seoul National University Press.  
  
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Mataji Umemura. eds. 1988. _Ky� nihon   
shokuminchi keizai t�kei_. Tokyo: Toyo keizai shuppansha.  
  
Suh, Sang-Chul. 1978. _Growth and Structural Changes in the Korean   
Economy, 1910-1940_. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.  
  
Young, Alwyn. 1995. "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the   
Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience."   
_Quarterly Journal of Economics_ 110 (3): 641-80.  
  
  
Myung Soo Cha is Professor at School of Economics and Finance,   
Yeungnam University. He is currently working on the pre-colonial   
demographic history of Korea and the spread of modern education in   
colonial Korea.  
  
Copyright (c) 2006 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be   
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to   
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the   
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).   
Published by EH.Net (October 2006). All EH.Net reviews are archived   
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.  
  
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW  --------------  
EH.Net-Review mailing list  
[log in to unmask]  
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review  
  

ATOM RSS1 RSS2