------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (February 2007)
Cristiano Antonelli, Dominique Foray, Bronwyn H. Hall and W. Edward
Steinmueller, editors, _New Frontiers in the Economics of Innovation
and New Technology: Essays in Honour of Paul A. David_. Cheltenham,
UK: Edward Elgar, 2006. vii + 485 pp. $160 (cloth), ISBN:
1-84376-631-0.
Reviewed for EH.NET by James Bessen, Boston University School of Law.
This festschrift of fifteen papers (plus an introduction and a
postscript) reflects the breadth of Paul David's work, both in the
range of subjects and in the methods used. The postscript, written by
Dominique Foray, compares David's work to a theatrical performance
that includes roles for Galileo and Edison, as well as Pomo Indians
and !Kung bushmen, nymphs, reapers and robots, sex, blood and more.
The collection in the book, no less broad (although probably less
theatrical), has something for everyone.
The papers are grouped into three sections, reflecting important
themes in David's work: path dependence, the economics of knowledge
and the diffusion of innovation. The significance of David's
contributions in each of these areas is developed in the introductory
essay by the editors and this provides a general, but brief,
introduction to his large body of work.
The first chapter, by Andrea P. Bassanini and Giovanni Dosi explores
why technology markets tend to be monopolies. This paper presents a
theoretical model to challenge Brian Arthur's (1989) widely-cited
model of competing technologies. Arthur's model has been used to
argue that technological monopolies result from unbounded increasing
returns. The paper shows that Arthur's result is not general, but
follows instead from specific assumptions of linearity and limited
heterogeneity among agents. The authors do find, however, that
increasing returns combined with a high rate of technological change
frequently generate stable near-monopolies in a more general model.
Cristiano Antonelli, in the second chapter, develops a high level
overview of different kinds of technological path dependence and
relates this to issues of dynamic economic efficiency.
Franco Malerba and Luigi Orsenigo study the evolution of the
pharmaceutical industry, looking at the interrelations between
technology, regulation and market structure. They begin with a very
nice summary of the development of pharmaceutical search technology
over the past fifty years, noting cross-country differences in
regulation and differences in the roles of imitative firms and market
leaders. They follow this with a simulation model for the "random
screening" era that reproduces some of these relationships.
John Cantwell uses patent data in an innovative way to explore path
dependency of large firms regarding their choices of technological
specialization. These firms maintained patterns of specialization --
that is, high levels of patenting relative to their industry peers in
certain specialties -- for periods of sixty years or longer.
Interestingly, Cantwell also finds some general trends in
technological diversification: the large firms in chemical and
electrical industries initially increased their diversification,
followed, over the last several decades, by a trend toward greater
technological concentration.
Two papers, one by G. M. Peter Swann and one by Robin Cowan, look at
issues of path dependency in tastes for art. Swann uses correlations
in auction prices for the paintings of different artists to map these
relationships. Cowan models the cyclical nature of changes in these
relationships.
Beginning the section on the economics of knowledge, W. Edward
Steinmueller picks up on Paul David's theme of organization and
learning. He looks at historical examples, including the transitions
from craft organization to the American system of manufactures to
Fordism to GM's "flexible mass production" to inform a discussion of
current-day issues of learning and organization in the use of
information technology to enhance product variety.
Dominique Foray and Lilian Hilaire Perez cover some less familiar
history, comparing Paul David's "open science" with the "open
technology" of the Lyon silk industry, which bore some similarities
to examples of shared innovation discussed by Allen, von Hippel and
others. Lyon established a sophisticated system of rewards for
inventors with incentives to share their knowledge. This led to an
extended period inventiveness. In contrast, the British silk
industry, where a larger share of inventions was patented, was
relatively backward. Foray and Hilaire Perez make a very useful
comparison between the features of the Lyon system and those of open
science.
Jacques Mairesse and Laure Turner directly explore the nature of
scientific collaboration by using data on co-publication to measure
the intensity of collaboration. Using this measure, they investigate
how the intensity of collaboration varies with geographical location
and technological specialization.
Patrick Cohendet and Ash Amin look at knowledge and the nature of the
firm, stressing interactions between "epistemic communities" and
"communities of practice" within the firm.
Ashish Arora, Andrea Fosfuri and Alfonso Gambardella ask how
institutions affect the creation and development of markets for
technology. In numerous papers and a book (2001), these authors have
explored aspects of technology markets. Here, with an eye toward
policy, they look specifically at the roles of standards,
well-defined property rights and institutions that encourage
risk-taking. The article provides a nice overview of a large range of
policy-related issues from an institutional perspective. At times the
authors seem a bit too enthusiastic. For example: "It is difficult to
think that a market ... could ever function properly without property
rights ..." I suspect that economic historians might think of
examples of trade pre-dating property rights or examples of illicit
trade outside the realm of property rights. Nevertheless, the article
provides a useful overview.
Arora, Fosfuri and Gambardella argue that global technology markets
allow small countries to specialize in technology fields in an
international division of innovative labor. Stefano Brusoni and Aldo
Geuna explore patterns of national specialization and also the
integration of different types of technical knowledge. They develop
indices of specialization similar to those used by Cantwell in the
paper discussed above, but based on data of peer-reviewed papers in
chemistry and pharmacology instead of patent data. They also measure
the integration of knowledge across areas of basic research, applied
research and applied technology and engineering. They find that large
European nations do not integrate basic research into pharmaceutical
technology as well as the U.S. does; they propose that this explains
why EU R&D managers in pharmaceuticals rely on U.S. research. They
also claim, perhaps controversially, that their measures might serve
as a policy guides -- governments might facilitate national
specialization by supporting integrated knowledge development.
The book's section on the diffusion of innovation begins with a
chapter by Bronwyn Hall and Manuel Trajtenberg that reports on
attempts to identify General Purpose Technologies using patent
statistics. Paul David (1990) persuasively argues that the diffusion
of electric motors one hundred years ago bears important similarities
to the diffusion of computer technology today. Both have been called
General Purpose Technologies (GPT), but some researchers have felt
that too many technologies can be called GPTs for the term to be a
useful analytical tool. The authors of this paper explore the use of
a variety of statistics based on patent citations to see if they can
derive a measure of "generality" and identify GPTs. Their results are
mixed. Using a combination of statistics, they identify twenty highly
ranked patents; most are related to using computers, especially for
interacting and working at a distance. These technologies seem to fit
the intuitive description of GPTs. On the other hand, the authors
note several possible biases that may have influenced this result.
The next chapter, by Luis M. B. Cabral presents a theoretical model
of technology diffusion that includes adopter heterogeneity (like
David's 1969 model) and also network effects.
In the final chapter, Paul Stoneman and Otto Toivanen also build a
model of technology diffusion, this one based on a real options
approach. They then apply this model to data on international
diffusion of robot technology, using a sophisticated econometric
model. They use the estimated model to conduct policy
thought-experiments, for example, testing the effects of
macro-economic stability on a nation's diffusion rate for robot
technology.
The research in this book exhibits a wide variety of methods, topics
and styles. Few readers will find all of the contributions worthwhile
or interesting. But few who have an interest in technological
innovation will fail to find something of value.
References:
Arora, Ashish, Andrea Fosfuri and Alfonso Gambardella (2001),
_Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate
Strategy_, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Arthur, W. Brian (1989), "Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns,
and Lock-in by Historical Events," _Economics Journal_ 99: 116-31.
David, Paul A. (1969), "A Contribution to the Theory of Diffusion,"
Research Center in Economic Growth, Memorandum No. 71, Stanford
University.
David, Paul A. (1990), "The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical
Perspective on the Modern Productivity Paradox," _American Economic
Review_ 80: 355-61.
James Bessen, Lecturer in Law, Boston University School of Law and
Director, Research on Innovation has, following Paul David, written
about learning-by-doing in "Technology and Learning by Factory
Workers: The Stretch-Out at Lowell, 1842," _Journal of Economic
History_ (2003). He is a former innovator and entrepreneur who wrote
one of the first desktop publishing programs. Now he writes about
technological innovation and patents. Current works include (with
Eric Maskin) "Sequential Innovation, Patents, and Imitation," RAND
(2007); (with Robert M. Hunt) "An Empirical Look at Software
Patents," _Journal of Economics and Management Strategy_ (2007) and a
book (with Michael J. Meurer), _Do Patents Work? The Empirical
Evidence That Today's Patents Fail as Property and Discourage
Innovation, and How They Might Be Fixed_ (forthcoming 2008).
Copyright (c) 2007 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).
Published by EH.Net (February 2007). All EH.Net reviews are archived
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
[log in to unmask]
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review
|