------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (January 2005)
F. M. Scherer, _Quarter Notes and Bank Notes: The Economics of Music
Composition the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries_. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 2004. x + 264 pp. $35 (cloth), ISBN:
0-691-11621-0.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Fran=E7ois R. Velde, Federal Reserve Bank of Chica=
go.
Among lovers of classical music, there are those who recognize in the
immortal works they so admire the purest manifestation of man's
genius striving to manifest the divine and touch the soul. And then,
there are the economists.
F. M. Scherer, Aetna Professor Emeritus in the John F. Kennedy School
of Government, Harvard University, and visiting professor at
Haverford College, is one of those music-loving economists, who
cannot help but see that the music he loves is, after all, an output
like many others, and cannot help but ask how this output was
produced, by whom, facing what prices and making what trade-offs, in
what kind of markets. This book contains his answers, a bold raid by
an economist into the subject matter of musicologists, but one that
economic historians would be the last to reprove, and should be the
first to imitate.
Scherer has much material to work with: composers have been the
subject of historical research and biographies, some of it
particularly directed at the business aspects of composing and
performing (such as the work of Milhous and Hume on Handel's
finances). Scherer has delved deeply into this material, selecting 50
composers whose biographies he read and from which he has selected
many enlightening anecdotes.
But quantitative analysis, guided by economic thinking, is the
comparative advantage of the economist. The substance of the book,
accordingly, consists of the analysis of a data-set constructed by
the author.
Scherer took all composers born between 1650 and 1850, listed in the
_Schwann Opus_ Fall 1996 catalogue of recorded music, and whom he was
able to match with biographical entries in the _New Grove_. The
Schwann catalogue provided both the sample selection tool and the
measure of musical output (the length of listings); the _Grove_ and
additional documentation provided personal characteristics (dates and
location of birth and death, type and level of education and
training, years spent in various locations, type and duration of
employment).
The obvious weakness of the data-set appears both in the selection of
composers and the in measure of output. The choice of composers
reflects the availability to (and tastes of) North American music
lovers of the last half-century. Moreover, musical "output" measures
the number of recordings, not the number of recorded works, let alone
the number of works written. Scherer wants to interpret this as
output weighted by quality, or at least durability. This
interpretation assigns a measure of reliability to the tastes
reflected in the 1996 catalog. The same exercise today (albeit not
with the _Schwann_, which disappeared several years ago) could well
yield a quite different sample, because of the "early music" revival
and rising interest in hitherto neglected composers. Scherer mentions
that only three recordings of Salieri's operas were listed in Schwann
in 1996: since then, Salieri's operatic "output" has tripled (and,
with three dozen unrecorded operas, it has room to grow)!
Not only does the author fully acknowledge this weakness, he
constantly reminds the reader of it, when appropriate. And I would
not be overly concerned about the bias in the measure of output,
since the analysis rests mostly on the numbers of composers in
various categories, rather than their output (regressions with this
output on the left-hand side don't tend to yield significant
results). But the selection bias itself is worrisome, particularly in
opera, where the phenomenally prolific composers of the eighteenth
century leave barely a trace in recordings today, for obvious reasons
of costs.
Be that as it may, Scherer proceeds to make full use of the sample he
has painstakingly constructed, and does so, alternating graphical
displays and regression analysis (with the estimates consigned in
endnotes for general readability), and qualitative evidence taken
from the biographies of the composers. Some anecdotes might already
be familiar from recording liner notes, but the vast and rich array
assembled here, if it does not prove or disprove the kinds of
hypotheses economists test, nevertheless gives texture and context, a
good feel for the reality of composers' working lives.
After a good general overview of the historical and economic
background and a description of the music-producing sector, Scherer
asks the questions that naturally come to mind, on origins and
backgrounds, education and training, the nature of careers and
employment, geographic mobility, the trade-offs faced, the rewards
that could be expected, and the degree of financial success that
could be hoped for. An additional chapter looks into more detail at
the economics of music publishing.
Among the interesting findings of chapters 3, 5, and 6, Scherer shows
that the transition from long-term employment relationships to
market-oriented activity was much more gradual than is frequently
asserted. While support from nobility and church collapsed after
1800, composers had already largely begun to shift toward freelance
composing and performing in the eighteenth century (comparing
employment within Germany between merchant cities and court-dominated
principalities confirms this). In the geography of music, Austria
(modern-day borders) overwhelmingly dominates the eighteenth century,
both in producing and in employing composers (the concern about
selection bias returns here). Thus, Scherer does not find support for
the hypothesis that political fragmentation in Germany led to
increased demand for music from princelings competing to decorate
their courts. Also, poorer nations tended to be exporters of musical
talent. This is perhaps less surprising after Scherer shows that the
type of training did not seem to matter much in what was still a
craft, hence poorer nations were not at a particular disadvantage in
accumulating this type of human capital. Interestingly, the mobility
of composers dropped very sharply in the nineteenth century, because
improved transportation and communication made it easier not to move
(change residence) in order to make a living.
Chapter 4, on the financial rewards and successes of composers, has
little in the way of concrete results, although Scherer is able to
document a very skewed distribution of rewards for musicians (being
mindful again of the selection bias: for those musicians whose music
we like enough to track down their probate inventories). But focusing
on the income derived from publishing, which is done in the final
chapter, proves fruitful. Many facts are gathered about the
technology and the costs of publishing music, and the evolution of
copyright, whose impact on the number of composers is examined.
Scherer also looks at the fees paid by publishers to Schumann and
Beethoven for their works, and measures how the fees per work rose
with cumulated output (presumably a reputation effect).
In the conclusion chapter, Scherer indulges in further speculation
about which system (court/church employment versus freelance)
produced better music. Modern debates over government subsidies for
the arts might find useful elements here, if the bias did not
interpose itself once more. The best Scherer could do with his data
is to make a statement about which system was better able to produce
music for the listeners two hundred years hence, not necessarily the
relevant question for today's taxpayer. The concluding chapter also
argues that a turning point in the 1920s (identified as the emergence
of radio and recordings, and documented by the collapse of piano
sales) led to a bifurcation between "serious" music and mass-market,
the former contracting Baumol's cost disease and now requiring
permanent transfusions of money to survive. These considerations are
a little hasty, as it is far from clear that the turning point is
correctly identified, and it is performance of old works, rather than
the composition of new works, that suffers from the cost disease. The
interesting question is: Why have we invented this concept of
"classical" music, i.e., music which by definition becomes more
expensive to perform? In most of the period that Scherer studies,
music died with its composer (if not before), and neither court nor
church subsidized the performance of centuries-old music (Allegri's
_Miserere_ notwithstanding).
If the book's only merit were to raise such questions, that would be
praise enough. But this book, designed to be accessible, deserves to
be read widely and foremost by his music-loving colleagues in the
economics profession. Even if Scherer has already done much of what
can be done with the material already gathered by musicologists,
there are still open questions (the economics of performing is
largely untouched). And this is, of course, not a flaw but an
invitation to follow in his footsteps.
Fran=E7ois R. Velde, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, is co-author of
_The Big Problem of Small Change_ (Princeton University Press, 2002),
and a music-lover
Copyright (c) 2005 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).
Published by EH.Net (January 2005). All EH.Net reviews are archived
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
[log in to unmask]
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review
|