====================== HES POSTING ==================
EH.NET BOOK REVIEW
Published by EH.NET (July 1997)
William J. Barber, _Designs Within Disorder: Franklin D. Roosevelt, the
Economists, and the Shaping of American Economic Policy, 1933-1945_. New
York: Cambridge University Press, 1996. ix + 178 pp. $44.95 (cloth),
ISBN: 0-051-56078-0.
Reviewed for EH.Net by Michael V. Namorato, Department of History,
University of Mississippi. <[log in to unmask]>
_Designs Within Disorder_ is William Barber's sequel to his
earlier work on economic thinking in the 1920s, entitled _From New Era to
New Deal: Herbert Hoover, the Economists, and American Economic Policy,
1921-1933_ (New York, 1985). Similar to his earlier study, _Designs
Within Disorder_ concentrates on what economists were saying during the
New Deal, how Franklin D. Roosevelt listened to and responded to their
suggestions, and the ultimate impact these economic thinkers had on
long-term federal economic policy. In the case of Franklin Roosevelt,
Barber believes that professional economists had a president who was
willing to listen to them and who was a "consumer" of what they had to
offer. Although not a great economic thinker, Roosevelt himself, in
Barber's opinion, was "an uncompromising champion of consumer sovereignty"
(p. 1). He provided those with more learning and understanding of
economic matters an opportunity to develop their ideas. Roosevelt's
Washington, in short, was a "laboratory affording economists an
opportunity to make hands-on contact with the world of events" (p. 2).
After much experimentation, the end result was an "Americanized version of
Keynesian macroeconomics" which became part and parcel of governmental
policy by the end of the 1930s. In this sense, the Rooseveltian years
were "a watershed in economic policy and in economic thinking" (p. 3).
To make his case, Barber details how economists affected Franklin
Roosevelt throughout his years in office. Beginning with the 1932
campaign, Barber argues that Roosevelt's Brains Trust would not have
received the endorsement of the American Economic Association. What Adolf
Berle, Rexford Tugwell, and Raymond Moley had in common besides
"geographical proximity" was their commitment to using the federal
government to address the economic crisis caused by the Great Depression.
Providing rather traditional and highly questionable critiques of what
Berle and Tugwell particularly were saying, Barber makes it clear that
these individuals were anti-Brandesians in their approach and thinking.
Perhaps more significantly, the author spends a considerable amount of
time examining what the Cornell group (George Warren and F.A. Pearson)
were calling for in regards to inflationary policies and what Irving
Fisher wanted to accomplish with his theories of reflation. Fisher, in
fact, not only did not approve of the Brains Trust and their
recommendations but he also was quite happy with Roosevelt's bombshell
message to the London Economic Conference. Instead, as Barber details,
Fisher called for a managed currency, breaking away from the gold
standard, and implementation of the Thomas amendment to the Agricultural
Adjustment Act. As for Franklin Roosevelt in the midst of these divergent
economic theories, Barber believes that the president showed "antipathy
towards the respectable economic thinking throughout 1933" and supported
structural interventions in industry and agriculture and in his monetary
experimentation.
Barber next turns his attention to the ideas of individuals like
Leon Henderson (National Recovery Administration), Leverett Lyon, Isador
Lubin (Commissioner of Labor Statistics), and Gardiner Means. His
analysis of the National Recovery Administration and Agricultural
Adjustment Administration is fairly traditional and his conclusion that
Roosevelt wanted to find a way to sustain governmental interventionism in
the economy with judicial approval is far from original in theory or
conception. The author does much better in explaining the differences
between the theoretical ideas of John M. Keynes and Irving Fisher,
although their impact on Roosevelt is lost in the argument itself. Barber
feels that the president was and remained "a fiscal conservative at heart"
anyway (p. 88). Barber argues that with the recession of 1937-1938 the
debate between the structuralists (a la Berle/Tugwell) and the monetarists
(a la Fisher and the Cornell Group) re-appeared. Despite Fisher's strong
case for 100 percent reserves, Roosevelt was more concerned with adding an
income orientation to macroeconomic policy with fiscal activism as a key
ingredient (p. 115).
Finally, in his last chapters, Barber takes his argument through
the later 1930s, World War II, and the immediate post-war era. Seeing
Harry Hopkins' appointment as Secretary of Commerce as a turning point
towards official acceptance of Keynesianism, Barber details how Hopkins
brought in young academics sympathetic to this approach, how the president
barely tolerated Thurman Arnold and his anti-trust movement, and how
people like John K. Galbraith in the Office of Price Administration helped
to mobilize America's wartime economy. In the end, however, individuals
like Galbraith left the New Deal. In fact, Barber concluded that the Full
Employment Act was more of a victory for the opponents of the Keynesian
approach than one would have suspected. Still, Keynesianism took hold
after 1945 only after it had infiltrated the universities (p. 171).
How does one assess _Designs Within Disorder_? On the positive
side, Barber has provided a very interesting perspective on the importance
of economic ideas and their champions/proponents at a critical moment in
American history. His coverage of the period, 1929-1947, is also very
thorough. He shows clearly how some economists perceived the _General
Theory_ of Keynes and what reaction it received within and outside of the
New Deal. And, most importantly, Barber provides a very detailed and
lucid exposition of Irving Fisher's ideas. Yet, just as there are strong
points in the study, there are some serious shortcomings. Barber's use of
primary sources is limited at best. He tends to take too many ideas and
quotes out of secondary works, some of which are rather dated. He also
has a tendency to reiterate traditional interpretations almost without
question. This is particularly true in his characterization of New
Dealers such as Rexford Tugwell. However, the more serious problems deal
with the individuals on whom he concentrates. Barber spends almost all of
his time on individuals who were either on the outside of the New Deal
looking in or who were on the inside of the New Deal but not very
influential. The best example here is Irving Fisher. While the author's
analysis of Fisher is quite good, the fact remains that Fisher never had a
role or position within the New Deal nor did any New Dealer in a position
of authority even listen to him. Barber, moreover, fails to recognize the
changing political environment within the New Deal itself. He never even
mentions individuals like Ben Cohen or Thomas Corcoran and the impact they
had on the president, especially in the way they filtered people and ideas
that they wanted Roosevelt to meet or hear about. Finally, Barber credits
Roosevelt with so much in terms of providing economists with an
opportunity to influence policy, but the president himself is seldom even
mentioned, no less analyzed in terms of his own thinking on what these
economists were telling him and his close advisors. Somehow, Roosevelt is
lost amidst the intellectual environment that Barber has created.
Nevertheless, although these shortcomings are serious, they do not
negate the overall contributions that _Designs Within Disorder_ make.
William Barber has written an interesting work on the importance of
economic thinking during the Great Depression years. In so doing, his
efforts remain worthwhile.
Michael V. Namorato
Department of History
University of Mississippi
Michael V. Namorato is author of _Rexford G. Tugwell: A Biography_ (1988).
Copyright (c) 1997 by EH.Net and H-Net, all rights reserved. This work
may be copied for non-profit educational use if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact
[log in to unmask] (Robert Whaples, Book Review Editor, EH.Net.
Telephone: 910-758-4916. Fax: 910-758-6028.)
============ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ============
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask]
|