SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Date:
Tue Dec 5 10:53:50 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (153 lines)
------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------  
Published by EH.NET (December 2006)  
  
Marc Flandreau _The Glitter of Gold: France, Bimetallism, and the   
Emergence of the International Gold Standard, 1848-1873_. New York:   
Oxford University Press, 2004. xxiii + 319 pp. $125 (cloth), ISBN:   
0-19-925786-8.  
  
Reviewed for EH.NET by Pierre Sicsic, Bank of France.  
  
  
This is a gem of a book. Marc Flandreau's rewritten published   
dissertation, _L'or du Monde_, explains how the bimetallic system was   
much more stable than is usually thought, and that it helped to   
buffer the shock of gold discovery in 1848 (meaning in that instance   
limiting inflation). Its eventual demise in 1873 was not the result   
of any economic cause (excess supply of silver, or efficiency gain of   
some kind), but of the French decision to try to impede the smooth   
German transition to a gold standard. Throughout the book Flandreau   
does not pull his punches, making clear his many disagreements with   
previous scholars.  
  
The introduction makes the very important point that France in the   
mid century was a very large country in terms of specie holdings (45   
percent of its seven-country sample). Then a general equilibrium   
model is set up in Chapter 1 with four demands: monetary and   
non-monetary demands for gold and silver. It is shown that there is a   
range of indeterminate bimetallic equilibria, and therefore that   
there is no knife-edge instability in a bimetallic system, provided   
one was lucky enough not to set the official silver/gold price   
outside of the equilibria range.  
  
Chapter 2 shows that gold and silver circulated together in France,   
if not in Paris, using the specie surveys (Chapter 4 deals with the   
same issue by estimating France's specie holdings from 1840 to 1878).   
France was not in a de facto gold standard after 1848. In the same   
chapter, using the Rothschild archives, internal arbitrage   
gold-silver points are computed. Together with the market price in   
Paris, they are consistent with some silver remaining in circulation   
in some parts of the country. This is economic history at its best.   
First show that some interesting outcome is theoretically possible,   
then show first that it actually happened and second explain how it   
made empirical sense that it did happen. Chapter 3 shows that silver   
was exported and gold imported into France and examines the economics   
of the exchange rate.  
  
Chapter 5 looks at the Banque de France's policy of purchasing gold   
and making payments in silver, and concludes that this policy was   
merely "surfing on a market wave" - that is following market signals.   
Chapter 6 depicts the business plan of the old Haute Banque   
(Rothschild), which involved arbitrage between markets (Paris and   
London), as well as trading in local markets and the industrial   
activity of minting.  
  
Chapter 7 starts by quoting inflationary fears in the mid 1850s after   
the gold finds in California and Australia. Then it explains that the   
net goods exports had to balance the specie flows, and that the goods   
flows are consistent with a wealth effect enriching people from   
countries were gold was found. The model of Chapter 1 is then   
estimated with France monetary holdings and world stocks of the two   
metals. The "lost secret" of bimetallism's stability shows up in the   
variables used for this estimation. There was a sustained production   
of silver, 5 billion francs vs. 12 billion francs of gold were mined   
in the twenty years up to 1870, while the gold stock held in France   
increased from 1 to 6 billion francs and the silver stock decreased   
from 2.5 to 1 billion francs. Bimetallism was indeed a remarkably   
supple system.  
  
Why then did bimetallism come to an end? Chapter 8 looks at the usual   
explanations. Using simulations of his model, Flandreau dismisses the   
excess supply of silver - even after the German shift to gold. German   
holdings in silver were 1.9 billion francs. The sound money view   
according to which gold standard was less inflationary than   
bimetallism is dismissed because of anachronism: in the   
mid-nineteenth century, the gold standard was inflationary. Finally   
the transaction cost argument is refuted because small change was   
indeed provided by coins with a lower silver content, and because the   
freight and insurance cost of bullion shipment was linked to the   
value and not to the weight of the shipment.  
  
France decided to demonetize silver to bother Germany, which had to   
unload its silver when it adopted of the gold standard. Germany's   
adoption was made possible by the 5 billion franc war indemnity paid   
in international bills, most of them convertible into gold. In this   
coordination problem (i.e., Franco-German rivalry) lies the reason of   
the accidental demise of bimetallism. At this junction one would like   
to be told why Germany decided to shift to the gold standard.  
  
Two points are made in the conclusion. The first one is that global   
financial integration existed much before the gold standard. This is   
true for co-movements of interest rates and bullion flows. This is   
not as true for financial flows. The second one is that the gold   
standard enabled concentration of bullion holdings in central banks.   
Thus the primary responsibility for managing the global monetary   
system was taken away from private concerns (the "market"). It opened   
the way to the nationalization of money, and macroeconomic rules   
became essential: "the question revolved on the 'credibility' of   
monetary institutions, which boiled down to making sure that they   
behaved as though the did not exist." In the end Flandreau concludes   
that the gold standard was modern, even though private arbitrages   
under bimetallism were pretty sophisticated, because it opened the   
way to macroeconomic monetary policy, and was bound to give way to   
managed currency.  
  
I have a slight disagreement with Flandreau about his criticism of   
the fundamentals theory of the end of bimetallism. While I am   
convinced that bimetallism could have been maintained in France (and   
in the U.S.) in 1873, I think the fundamentals theory would have   
eventually led to its end at a 15.5 (or 16) to 1 relative price after   
1890. It would be interesting to keep simulating the model used in   
the book with metal output up to 1895. Moreover, as stated in chapter   
1, monetary demand depends on the expected purchasing power of the   
specie balances. Therefore, an expected surge of silver mining might   
lead to an expected loss of purchasing power of silver, and decline   
in silver money demand. With perfect foresight, bimetallism breaks   
down as soon as the silver output surge is expected.  
  
Finally, after reading _The Glitter of Gold_ I went back to the   
famous "crime of 1873" counterfactual by Milton Friedman. I now   
believe that the most relevant counterfactual is that the U.S. and   
France would have remained on bimetallism, for less than twenty   
years. Then the "sophisticated" simulation with the silver price   
going down to 23.7 is much less likely than the 16 to 1 simulation. I   
find it interesting that the deflation in this (likely) simulation   
also provided by Friedman is very close to the actual deflation,   
while it disappears in the "sophisticated" simulation.  
  
Everyone interested in monetary history or in mid-nineteenth century   
French economic history should read Marc Flandreau's book. If in a   
hurry and with some prior knowledge of the bimetallic issues, read   
the first two chapters, jump to Chapter 7 parts 3 to 5, and then to   
Chapter 8 part 2 and the conclusion.  
  
  
Pierre Sicsic, who is director of the Balance of Payments in the Bank   
of France, is the author (with Pierre-Cyrille Hautcoeur) of "Threat   
of a Capital Levy, Expected Devaluation and Interest Rates in France   
during the Interwar Period," _European Review of Economic History_,   
1999.  
  
Copyright (c) 2006 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be   
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to   
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the   
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).   
Published by EH.Net (December 2006). All EH.Net reviews are archived   
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.  
  
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW  --------------  
EH.Net-Review mailing list  
[log in to unmask]  
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review  
  

ATOM RSS1 RSS2