Anthony Waterman wrote:
> I appreciate the trouble that Dierdre McCloskey, Eric Schliesser and
> Pat Gunning have taken to respond to my long-winded comments on HET. I
> agree with much of what each has said, and could probably reach even
> greater agreement if we were to meet and talk. But I still feel that
> I have failed to make clear just why what I call HEA is a significant
> component of the intellectual enterprise we label 'economics', and why
> what I call IH (which is what most of the participants in this
> discussion are most interested in) is not. I wonder if it would help
> to use an analogy? If so, what follows might serve as a vindication
> both of HEA and of its greatest practitioner, Paul Samuelson.
Anthony gives a witty illustration with a distinction between historical
pieces of information that are relevant for crafting a winning strategy
for the impending battle of North Africa and those that are not. He
concludes:
> What I am interested in is tactics, and if by making rational
> reconstructions of byegone battles I can learn things that will make
> me a better tactician, that's what I'm going to do.
I think what some of Samuelson's critics are saying is that he hasn't
done a good enough "rational reconstruction" of bygone battles. Take,
for example, the battle over the role of saving (rather than
consumption) in economic growth during the classical period. Smith,
Say, Ricardo, (Malthus) and J.S. Mill all emphasized that saving
promotes economic growth whiles consumption (or current enjoyment by
income earners) retards it. J.M Keynes comes along in 1930
(_Treatise_) with his paradox of thrift (saving) argument, further
elaborated in his1936 _General Theory_ in contradiction to classical
theory. Wasn't it bad rational reconstruction for Samuelson to have
crafted the Keynesian argument in terms of algebra and geometry for
millions of students to learn the false claim that there is such a thing
as a paradox of thrift in their macroeconomics textbooks (I learned that
from Samuelson's _Economics_ in the late 1960s), only perhaps to
struggle to learn the contra-argument in courses in development economics?
I could cite some other examples in macroeconomics where Samuelson could
have done a better job at rational reconstruction of bygone battles.
I'm thus left wondering about the usefulness of the history of economic
analysis (HEA), of which Samuelson is the greatest practitioner,
according to Anthony, as against that of intellectual history (IH), in
promoting scientific economics in contrast to scientism.
James Ahiakpor
|