SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Robert Leeson <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Sun, 8 May 2011 06:17:07 -0700
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (210 lines)
With respect to the reason why the Economics Department at the University of Chicago refused to accept Hayek: Milton Friedman told Bruce Caldwell (2000) “My understanding is that this was because, at that stage, he really wasn’t doing any economics.” (There may also have been some resistance to outside pressure). It appears that the location doubts (which side of the Popperian demarcation line?) post-date Hayek's fifth floor location.  

Friedman (in print, at least) concluded that the Austrian business cycle model was dangerous "nonsense" in 1964, after Hayek left Chicago (Monetary Studies of the National Bureau, The National Bureau Enters Its 45th Year, 44th Annual Report, 7-25; Reprinted in Friedman, 1969, The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, Chicago: Aldine).  

In an interview with David Levy, Arnold Harberger (1999) observed “a great difference in focus between Hayek (the Austrians) and Chicago as a whole. I really respect and revere those guys. I am not one of them, but I think I once said that if somebody wants to approach economics as a religion, the Austrian approach is about as good as you can get.”

Friedman also reflected on the “so-called Austrians, or von Misesians … Because their philosophy which admits no role whatsoever for empirical evidence—it’s entirely introspective—leads to an attitude of human intolerance. I think anybody who holds that methodological view either is to begin with, or ultimately becomes, an intolerant human being. And the reason is very simple. If you and I disagree about a proposition, the question is how do we resolve our difference? If we adopt a Misesian methodological point of view, the only way we can resolve our difference is by arguing with one another. I know it from what’s inside me, you know it from what’s inside you, and so you have to persuade me that I’m wrong, or I have to persuade you that I’m right. There is no other appeal. And so ultimately we have to get to fighting … that’s why I think that their praxeological philosophy leads to intolerance. You’ll notice that Mises himself was a highly intolerant person. Ayn Rand was a highly intolerant person. As he’s become older, Popper has become an intolerant person." 

Friedman believed that Chicago semi-rescued Hayek from intolerance: "Hayek is a very interesting case, because I think Chicago in particular had a sufficient influence on him so as to move him away and he is not nearly as intolerant as the other von Misesians. Same thing was true of Fritz Machlup, who was another disciple of von Mises, but neither of them were anything like as intolerant as von Mises himself. But this crew of people down at the Mises Institute [at Auburn University] … They’re just as intolerant a bunch as you can find. A coin has two sides. Von Mises’ greatness as an economist, his extraordinary influence on a wide range of followers, the hero-worship he attracted — all these derived from his inflexible honesty, with the “inflexible” element as important as the “honesty” element. But the other side of that coin was intransigence, even dogmatism, that bordered on intolerance for anyone who did not wholly agree with him." 

There is also the related issue of the association between the mental illness which afflicted that generation of Austrians and their intolerance (and in some instances hysteria). Economists are not trained to express a professional judgement on such matters. But it was a tragedy that Mises and Henry Simons (a fellow libertarian) were not apparently adequately diagnosed.  Hayek, of course, blamed his own lengthy illness on medical misdiagnosis.   

Does the self-appointed role of Defenders of Civilisation legitimise the argumentum ad hominem fallacy that some Austrians embrace (and which should be enough to exclude them from scientific discourse)?  Does it also legitimise the expression of anger and intolerance which - according to Margrit Mises (1984, 36) - had nothing to do Defending Civilisation but was instead caused by mental illness?
    
Robert Leeson 

----- Original Message -----
From: "Steve Horwitz" <[log in to unmask]>
To: [log in to unmask]
Sent: Sunday, 8 May, 2011 5:53:12 AM
Subject: Re: [SHOE] RVW -- Diamond on Emmett, ed., _The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics _




To add to Robert’s point:  Hayek’s appointment at Chicago was to the Committee on Social Thought precisely because the Economics department didn’t wish to hire him, presumably because he was seen as insufficiently “scientific” for them.  At least that’s the story.  Whatever the reason, it certainly suggests, aside from the very important differences between Hayek’s approach and that of the Chicago School that can be gleaned from even a cursory look at Hayek’s work, the Chicagoans apparently didn’t consider him one of them. 

  

Steve Horwitz 

  



From: Societies for the History of Economics [mailto:[log in to unmask]] On Behalf Of Robert Nadeau 
Sent: Saturday, May 07, 2011 12:21 PM 
To: [log in to unmask] 
Subject: Re: [SHOE] RVW -- Diamond on Emmett, ed., _The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics _ 

  

One should not assume, as Prof. Diamond does, that F.A. Hayek was ever a formal member of the Chicago School of Economics. 

Robert Nadeau 


Le 11-05-06 22:38, « Robert Leeson » < [log in to unmask] > a écrit : 

The words "more complete, measured, and rigorously developed synthesis" should not be applied to Overtveldt's error-ridden hagiography. 

Robert Leeson 

----- Original Message ----- 
From: "Bradley R. Turner" < [log in to unmask] > 
To: [log in to unmask] 
Sent: Saturday, 7 May, 2011 8:35:18 AM 
Subject: Re: [SHOE] RVW -- Diamond on Emmett, ed., _The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics _ 

For a more complete, measured, and rigorously developed synthesis, see The Chicago School: How the University of Chicago Assembled the Thinkers who Revolutionized Economics and Business (2007), by Johan Van Overtveldt. 


Friedman, on the cover, describes it as "Thorough and extraordinarily well informed." 



On Fri, May 6, 2011 at 7:17 PM, Humberto Barreto < [log in to unmask] > wrote: 


------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW ------ 
Title: The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics 

Published by EH.NET (May 2011) 

Ross B. Emmett, editor, /The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of 
Economics/. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2010. xi + 350 pp. $200 
(hardcover), ISBN: 978-1-84064-874-4 

Reviewed for EH.Net by Arthur M. Diamond, Jr., Department of Economics, 
University of Nebraska at Omaha. 

The Chicago School of economics has been described in a variety of ways.  In 
the current volume, a useful description is given in the essay of Bruce 
Kaufman who emphasizes “... a deep commitment to rigorous scholarship and 
open academic debate, an uncompromising belief in the usefulness and insight 
of neoclassical price theory, and a normative position that favors and 
promotes economic liberalism and free markets”  (p. 133). 

The volume has been edited by Ross Emmett, a Michigan State historian of 
economic thought whose previous research has focused on early Chicago 
economist Frank Knight.  About two-thirds of the volume consists of fifteen 
“Essays on the Chicago School” in Part 1.  The remaining third of the 
volume, in Part 2, consists of nineteen brief profiles of “Some Chicago 
Economists.” 

The only essay that attempts any kind of broad overview of the volume is 
Emmett’s four-page introduction.  His essay briefly establishes the 
historical context of the Chicago School and points us toward some of the 
earlier literature in the history of economic thought that discusses the 
Chicago School.  But it does not attempt to summarize the diverse messages 
of the essays of the volume, let alone try to synthesize these messages into 
any overarching conclusions. 

Synthesis would have been difficult, if not impossible, because of the 
apparent absence of any consistent criteria for selection of the contents. 
This volume appears to be opportunistic in the sense that the contributors 
often were culled from those who attended conferences with the editor on the 
Chicago School, and the editor has left the contributors considerable leeway 
in the length, content and style of what they have contributed.  Emmett 
openly admits (p. 3) that some important topics have been left out of the 
“Essays” section of the volume.  But he does not identify the most 
glaring omission:  the contributions of George Stigler and his colleagues, 
such as Brozen, Demsetz and Peltzman, to industrial organization and the 
economics of regulation. 

Most of the essays adopt a neutral, expository stance, reporting the main 
research contributions of various Chicago scholars on various topics.  Some 
of these essays are written by scholars with some connection to the Chicago 
School, and some simply by scholars with an interest in the history of 
economic thought.  Among the expository essays, economic historians will 
especially appreciate David Mitch’s chronicle of Chicago’s contributions 
to economic history, with some discussion of Earl Hamilton, and special 
attention to Fogel and McCloskey; and Hugh Rockoff’s extensive account of 
the genesis and findings of Friedman and Schwartz’s tour de force in /A 
Monetary History of the United States/. 

Some of the other expository essays are fairly detailed accounts of aspects 
of the Chicago School, e.g., Daniel Hammond’s thorough account of Friedman 
and Stigler’s development of Chicago price theory; and Daniel Benjamin’s 
account of the three most important papers by Armen Alchian. Others paint 
with a broader brush, but provide useful overviews of their topics, e.g., 
Steven Medema’s account of the development of Chicago law and economics; H. 
Spencer Banzhaf’s account of the development of Chicago welfare economics; 
and Gordon Brady’s account of the Chicago School “roots” of the 
Virginia School that was James Buchanan’s early intellectual home. 

Parts of Eric Schliesser’s essay are less expository and more tendentious 
-- implying that Milton Friedman was indirectly responsible for the worst 
that Pinochet did in Chile.  When Schliesser’s essay was earlier presented 
to the American Economic Association, Deirdre McCloskey powerfully and 
persuasively defended Friedman.  Part of McCloskey’s defense was her 
report of a Chicago economics faculty meeting she attended, where Friedman 
had successfully argued for turning down funding that had been offered to the 
department from a repressive regime.  But in this volume, Schliesser’s 
critique of Chicago is left unanswered.  The volume would have been better 
if it had included both sides. 

Nineteen economists are included in the profiles of the “Some Chicago 
Economists” part of the volume.  The basis for selecting the nineteen is 
not obvious.  If we limit ourselves to economists who fit Kaufman’s 
description of the Chicago School, then it is hard to understand the absence 
of Nobel-Prize-winning Chicago economists Milton Friedman (yes, /Milton 
Friedman/ is absent), Robert Lucas, James Heckman, James Buchanan, Robert 
Mundell, Merton Miller and Robert Fogel.  And if we adopt a broader concept 
of the Chicago School, as Emmett seems to do when he includes Paul Douglas 
among his nineteen, then it is also hard to understand the absence of 
Thorstein Veblen (an early editor of Chicago’s /Journal of Political 
Economy/), and F.A. Hayek. 

The profiles that are included often have useful information.  But much of 
importance is omitted, sometimes due to the brevity of the profiles, and 
sometimes due to the agendas of the profile authors. The four pages on George 
Stigler, for instance, focus primarily on his biography, who he associated 
with, and a selection of his political views; but give scant attention to his 
wit, his erudition, and his contributions to research, especially in the area 
of the history of economic thought.  And to make matters worse, the 
bibliography to the profile neglects to reference key works that do focus 
mainly on Stigler’s research.  (The Wikipedia entry on Stigler does a 
better job.) 

But on the other hand, it was good to see Evelyn Forget’s profile of 
Margaret Reid included in “Some Chicago Economists.”  When I was a 
graduate student at Chicago, Reid had been long retired, but she still 
regularly attended Becker’s workshop, and still pursued her research.  In 
those days, graduate students would spend long hours at the computer center 
with their decks of IBM punch cards, to wait their turn to run their 
regressions on the mainframe.  And it did not entirely escape our attention 
that Margaret Reid was there too, with her deck of cards, waiting her turn. 
Her presence and her persistence taught us something about the values of the 
Chicago School --something that Klamer and Colander would later reconfirm in 
their interviews with graduate students in /The Making of an Economist/.  At 
Chicago, economic research was not just some puzzle-solving game by which you 
earned your living; not something you retired from; economics was a calling 
that mattered. 

References: 

Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. / A Monetary History of the 
United States, 1867-1960/, NBER Studies in Business Cycles.  Princeton: 
Princeton University Press, 1963. 

Klamer, Arjo, and David Colander. / The Making of an Economist/.  Boulder, 
CO: Westview Press, 1990. 

Arthur M. Diamond Jr. received three graduate degrees from the University of 
Chicago, and was a Post-Doctoral Fellow in economics at the University.  He 
has recently published several papers related to Schumpeter’s process of 
creative destruction and is at work on a book entitled /Openness to Creative 
Destruction/. [log in to unmask] . 

Copyright (c) 2011 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied 
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and 
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator 
( [log in to unmask] ). Published by EH.Net (May 2011). All EH.Net reviews 
are archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview . 

Geographic Location: North America 
Subject: History of Economic Thought; Methodology 
Time: 20th Century: Pre WWII, 20th Century: WWII and post-WWII 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2