SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Humberto Barreto <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Sat, 2 Oct 2010 16:52:01 -0400
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (87 lines)
------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW ------
Title: The Origins of English Financial Markets: Investment and Speculation
before the South Sea Bubble

Published by EH.NET (October 2010)

Anne L. Murphy, /The Origins of English Financial Markets: Investment and
Speculation before the South Sea Bubble./ New York: Cambridge University
Press, 2009. xiii + 283 pp. $99 (cloth), ISBN: 978-0-521-51994-6.

Reviewed for EH.NET by Stephen Quinn, Department of Economics, Texas
Christian University.

Anne Murphy’s /The Origins of English Financial Markets/ examines the
demand side of the English Financial Revolution.  Much has been written on
the surge in the supply of securities around 1700, but someone had to buy the
stuff. Murphy’s book tells the story of English investors in the 1690s –
a volatile period when England was an emerging market economy.

The first chapter shows that a corporate stock boom occurred in London before
the funded national debt and the Bank of England.  Investors learned about
stock transfers, dividends, initial public offerings, and corporate
bankruptcy before the state attempted to sell its new financial products in
the mid-1690s.

Chapters 2 and 3 revisit the revolution in English public finance and the
pamphleteering that went along with it.  In the process, Murphy finds that
investors valued resale liquidity even if the state was slow to
accommodate.  The author also argues that investors used the press to push
back against the government.  Murphy finds that creditors, “acted both to
call the government to account and, when necessary, in defence of their
property rights” (p. 61).  Put differently, Murphy casts investors as
active participants in the creation of credible sovereign debt.

Chapters 4 and 5 examine how advantageous market information was available
but required effort.  The financial press did provide a record of prices,
but more timely or nuanced information required investors to engage the
networks of information that entangled London.  Many small investors
understood that they were at the mercy of market insiders, and that
vulnerability contributed to the widespread distrust of financial
intermediaries.

Chapters 6 and 7 use archival sources to show how a small circle of
London-based brokers and dealers (called jobbers) did indeed dominate the
resale market for securities.  The social-economic and geographic frontiers
of the investing class were expanding, but Murphy argues that it was the rise
of market makers that buoyed demand for securities. Stocks that did not
secure a critical mass of intermediation slid into oblivion.  Much of this
compelling evidence comes from a detailed analysis of Bank of England stock
transfers.

Chapter 8 finishes the analysis by considering the in-betweens: investors who
were not broker-dealers and yet did not buy-and-hold either.  Again, Murphy
hits the archives to show that this active middle existed.  Many were
merchants redeploying capital when war limited traditional commercial
operations.  To me, Chapter 8 is too modest regarding the implications of
these active investors.  Again, the book establishes that an expanding
resale market drove the demand side of the English Financial Revolution, but
market makers need customers, yet most investors rarely bought or sold.
Active investors emerge as a necessary, if underappreciated, aspect of the
Financial Revolution.

Substantial archival work and an important focus make /The Origins of English
Financial Markets/ a substantial contribution to our understanding of the
English Financial Revolution.  The book is a must read for scholars of Early
Modern Britain. Others interested in development, now or in the past, will
find in the book a detailed example of how a successful financial system
actually emerged.

Stephen Quinn is the author of “Money, Finance and Capital Markets,” in
/The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain/, Volume I, edited by Floud
and Johnson, Cambridge University Press (2004): 147-74.  His recent work
with William Roberds on the Bank of Amsterdam includes “An Economic
Explanation of the Early Bank of Amsterdam,” in /The Origin and Development
of Financial Markets and Institutions/, edited by Atack and Neal, Cambridge
University Press (2009): 32-70.

Copyright (c) 2010 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator
([log in to unmask]). Published by EH.Net (October 2010). All EH.Net
reviews are archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.

Geographic Location: Europe
Subject: Financial Markets, Financial Institutions, and Monetary History
Time: 17th Century

ATOM RSS1 RSS2