Mime-Version: |
1.0 |
Sender: |
|
Subject: |
|
From: |
|
Date: |
Thu, 2 Apr 2009 13:25:36 -0400 |
Content-Transfer-Encoding: |
8bit |
Content-Type: |
text/plain; charset="iso-8859-1"; format=flowed |
Reply-To: |
|
Parts/Attachments: |
|
|
Smith introduces the real bills doctrine against
Hume’s quantity theory of money and hostility to
banks. It explains how banks can take liquidity
risks by granting credit (which had to be paid in
90 days) and issuing notes (which are payable at
demand). If the bank discounts real bills, the
cash reserve (necessary to pay notes at demand)
and he shareholders’ fund of the bank are
consolidated. If it discounts fictitious bills,
the cash reserve and the shareholders’ fund are encroached upon.
Again, Fullarton (1845) enriches the real bills
doctrine to contradict the quantity theory of the
Currency School. It is a part of the Banking
School analysis of the functioning of the
international gold standard system. The gold
point mechanism, the lender of last resort
function of the central bank and the managing of
bank rate are the complementary components of
Banking School analysis. Without the real bills
doctrine, the Banking School’s criticism of the
1844 Bank Act collapses. See Wicksell and Neil
message. But remember that the Bank Act was an
attempt to prevent the Bank taking liquidity risks.
Thornton’s criticism of the real bills doctrine
is different from Ricardian criticism. The real
bills doctrine developed by the American “credit
school” at the end of the 19 century is distinct
from the doctrine developed by the Banking School.
We must be careful when evaluating the real bills
doctrine. I’m not convinced that Smith and
Fullarton banking theories are totally irrelevant.
Jérôme de Boyer des Roches
|
|
|