SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Humberto Barreto <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Wed, 11 Dec 2019 08:54:59 -0600
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (560 lines)
nep-hpe  New Economics Papers on History and Philosophy of Economics
─────────────────────────────┐
Issue of 2019‒12‒09
28 papers chosen by
Erik Thomson (University of Manitoba)
 http://ep.repec.org/pth72

[Selections by Humberto Barreto for SHOE list.]


 1. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Eugenics and
     Socialist Thought in the Progressive Era: The Case of James Medbery
     Mackaye
   Foresti, Tiziana
 3. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - "Keynes, Mill
     and Say's Law: A Comment on Professor Ahiakpor's Mistaken Defence of Mill"
   Grieve, Roy H
 4. American Gothic: How Chicago Economics Distorts `Consumer Welfare` in
     Antitrust
   Mark Glick
 5. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - The
     Environmental Turn in Natural Resource Economics: John Krutilla and
     "Conservation Reconsidered"
   Banzhaf, H. Spencer
 6. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - READING KEYNES
     AT THE ZERO LOWER BOUND: THE GREAT DEPRESSION, THE LIQUIDITY TRAP, AND
     UNCONVENTIONAL POLICY
   Sutch, Richard
 7. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Keynes, Mill,
     and Say’s Law: A Comment on Roy Grieve’s Mistaken Criticisms of Mill
   Ahiakpor, James C.W.
 9. “Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - The
     Contribution of Robert Torrens to Ricardo’s Theory of Natural Wage”
   Rosell, Olivier
10. Keynes Between the Classics and Sraffa: on the Issue of the Numéraire
   M. Magnani
11. Journal of History of Economic Thought Preprints- Ricardo and
     Ricardians on the Order of Culivation
   , BIDARD
12. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Keynes, Public
     Debt and the Complex of Interest Rates
   Aspromourgos, Anthony
13. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Limits to
     Arbitrage and Interest Rates: A Debate Between Keynes, Hawtrey and Hicks
   BRILLANT, Lucy
14. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Hawtrey,
     Austerity, and the "Treasury View," 1918-25
   mattei, clara
15. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Sir James
     Steuart on the Origins of Commercial Nations
   Menudo, José M.
17. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Antonio De
     Viti De Marco, the principle of minimum means, and political competition
   Fossati, Amedeo; Montefiori, Marcello
18. How Behavioural Economics Relates to Psychology - Some Bibliographic
     Evidence
   Braesemann, Fabian
19. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Review of
     ​Karl Polanyi: A Life on the Left​
   Schumacher, Reinhard
21. The transformation of economic analysis at the Federal Reserve during
     the 1960s
   Acosta, Juan; Cherrier, Beatrice
22. Shortcomings of experimental economics to study human behavior: a
     reanalysis of Cohn et al. 2014, Nature 516, 86–89, ‘‘Business culture and
     dishonesty in the banking industry’’
   Hupé, Jean-Michel
23. Dobrogea School of Economics
   ARTENE, Alin
24. What is replication?
   Nosek, Brian A.; Errington, Timothy M.
25. The ordinary business of macroeconometric modeling: working on the
     Fed-MIT-Penn model (1964-1974)
   Cherrier, Beatrice; Backhouse, Roger
26. A Happy Choice: Wellbeing as the Goal of Government
   Frijters, Paul; Clark, Andrew E.; Krekel, Christian; Layard, Richard
27. Produire un fait scientifique: Beveridge et le Comité international
     d'histoire des prix
   Demade, Julien
28. Theories of the Causes of Poverty
   Brady, David

────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────

 1. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Eugenics and
     Socialist Thought in the Progressive Era: The Case of James Medbery
     Mackaye
   Foresti, Tiziana
  The article proposes an analysis of James MacKaye’s socialism and its
  relation to eugenics in the early years of the Progressive Era. In this
  respect, our work, showing as it does the pervasiveness of eugenics
  independently from traditional ideological boundaries, represents a further
  contribution to the Eugenics in the Progressive era debate inaugurated by
  Thomas Leonard’s Illiberal Reformers: Race, Eugenics, and American Economics
  in the Progressive Era (2016). At the same time, this paper contributes to
  the strand of literature that deals with the economic elaboration of the
  idea of differential capacities for happiness, of which the works of Levy
  and Peart represent the most recent examples. MacKaye is almost an unknown
  character today, but in his day he was quite influential and his peculiar
  brand of socialism deserves some critical attention.
   Date: 2018–03–25
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:tzcef&r=hpe

 3. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - "Keynes, Mill
     and Say's Law: A Comment on Professor Ahiakpor's Mistaken Defence of Mill"
   Grieve, Roy H
  This note is a reply to James Ahiakpor's critical blast against my 2016
  paper on the subject of Keynes, Mill and Say's Law. Professor Ahiakpor has
  apparently missed the point I was trying to make: his slings and arrows hit
  no targets.
   Date: 2018–01–03
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:43bmg&r=hpe

 4. American Gothic: How Chicago Economics Distorts `Consumer Welfare` in
     Antitrust
   Mark Glick (University of Utah)
  Since the publication of Robert Bork`s The Antitrust Paradox, lawyers,
  judges, and many economists have defended `Consumer welfare` (CW) as a
  standard for decisions about antitrust goals and enforcement priorities.
  This paper argues that the CW is actually an empty concept and is an
  inappropriate goal for antitrust. Welfare economists concede that there is
  no credible measurable link between price and output and human well-being.
  This means that the concept of CW does not legitimate limited antitrust
  enforcement, nor does it justify the exclusion of other antitrust goals that
  require more active enforcement practices. This paper contends that
  antitrust policy is not welfare based at all, and that if it were, antitrust
  policy and enforcement would differ significantly from the Chicago School
  vision. Without the fiction that economists can establish that in the short
  run lower price and higher output measurably increases welfare more than
  other goals, recent defenses of the CW standard resolve down to arguments
  based on unsupported assumptions.
   JEL: K21 L40 N12
   Keywords: U.S. Consumer Welfare, Goal of Antitrust Law, New Brandeis
    School, Chicago School of Economics.
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:thk:wpaper:99&r=hpe

 5. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - The
     Environmental Turn in Natural Resource Economics: John Krutilla and
     "Conservation Reconsidered"
   Banzhaf, H. Spencer
  Environmentalism in the United States historically has been divided into its
  utilitarian and preservationist impulses, represented by Gifford Pinchot and
  John Muir, respectively. Pinchot advocated conservation of natural resources
  to be used for human purposes; Muir advocated protection from humans, for
  nature's own sake. In the first half of the 20th century, natural re-source
  economics was firmly in Pinchot's side of that schism. That position began
  to change as the post-war environmental movement gained momentum. In
  particular, John Krutilla, an economist at Resources for the Future, pushed
  economics to the point that it could embrace Muir's vision as well as
  Pinchot's. Krutilla argued that if humans preferred a preserved state to a
  developed one, then such preferences were every bit as "economic." Either
  way, there were opportunity costs and an economic choice to be made.
   Date: 2018–05–21
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:ca7eb&r=hpe

 6. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - READING KEYNES
     AT THE ZERO LOWER BOUND: THE GREAT DEPRESSION, THE LIQUIDITY TRAP, AND
     UNCONVENTIONAL POLICY
   Sutch, Richard
  John Maynard Keynes’s analysis of the Great Depression has strong parallels
  to recent theorizing about the post-2008 Great Recession. There are also
  remarkable similarities between the two historical episodes: the collapse of
  demand for new fixed investment, the role of the zero-lower-bound liquidity
  trap in hampering conventional monetary policy, the multi-year period of
  near-zero short-term rates, and the protracted period of subnormal
  prosperity. A major difference between then and now that monetary
  authorities in the recent situation actively pursued an unconventional
  policy with massive purchases of long-term securities. Keynes couldn’t
  convince authorities of his era to pursue such a plan, but it was precisely
  the monetary policy he advocated for a depressed economy stuck at the zero
  lower bound of nominal interest rates.
   Date: 2018–03–13
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:vzykd&r=hpe

 7. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Keynes, Mill,
     and Say’s Law: A Comment on Roy Grieve’s Mistaken Criticisms of Mill
   Ahiakpor, James C.W.
  Employing different meanings of classical concepts of saving, capital,
  investment, and money, and incorrectly attributing the assumption of full
  employment of labor and a world of certainty to classical analysis, Keynes
  (1936) faulted Say’s Law as irrelevant to the real world. Roy Grieve (2016)
  ignores previous clarifications of Keynes’s misrepresentations and
  misunderstandings of Mill’s restatements of the law. He employs similar
  misrepresentations and misunderstandings of Mill’s explanations as Keynes.
  His model of Mill’s analysis is incapable of explaining how variations in
  relative prices, the value of money, and interest rates coordinate
  production, consumption and savings decisions in a monetary economy.
   Date: 2017–11–29
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:ys8dt&r=hpe


 9. “Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - The
     Contribution of Robert Torrens to Ricardo’s Theory of Natural Wage”
   Rosell, Olivier
  This paper reconsiders the anteriority of Torrens’ theory of natural wage to
  that of Ricardo. Ricardo was influenced by Torrens’ thinking when writing
  the chapter on “Wages” of the Principles. For many historians of economic
  thought, this influence is limited to Torrens’ focus on the sociocultural
  aspect of necessity goods, which determine the natural price of labor. While
  this interpretation is consistent with that of Ricardo, we argue that the
  anteriority of Torrens to Ricardo more generally focuses on the method used
  by the latter to justify the indexation of money wages on the money price of
  subsistence goods. Finally, this paper shows that the tribute paid to
  Torrens by Ricardo paradoxically explains the misunderstanding of his theory
  by posterity.
   Date: 2018–01–03
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:kxaed&r=hpe

10. Keynes Between the Classics and Sraffa: on the Issue of the Numéraire
   M. Magnani
  The paper sketches a coherent history of the choice of the measure standard
  from Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations to Sraffa’s Production of Commodities.
  As neither the Smithian labour commanded unit nor the Ricardian-Marxian
  labour embodied one provide a general solution to the dilemma concerning the
  finding of an invariable standard, the author shows the shortcomings of both
  methods in an analytically rigorous way. Several years later, the largely
  unacknowledged fourth chapter of the General Theory once again tackles the
  matter of measuring aggregate values adopting a net approach and introducing
  an ad hoc unit. Concerned by the inherent difficulties of the operation,
  Keynes starts from an harsh criticism towards Pigou’s notion of national
  dividend to end up asking himself a number of questions that makes him
  partially lean towards the later Sraffian approach as presented in
  Production of Commodities, though his stance is not fully compliant either
  with the premises or the aims of Piero Sraffa’s theoretical framework. In
  the final part, a general solution based on net labour productivity is
  considered.
   JEL: B12 B14 B24 B51
   Date: 2019–11
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bol:bodewp:wp1139&r=hpe

11. Journal of History of Economic Thought Preprints- Ricardo and
     Ricardians on the Order of Culivation
   , BIDARD
  The Ricardian dynamics are based on the study of the order of cultivation
  when demand increases. Sraffa criticized Ricardo for having assumed that the
  incoming method is defined by a natural order and stressed that the law of
  succession of methods is based on a profitability criterion. Then, in the
  case of intensive cultivation, the question is whether the incoming method
  is indeed more productive than the one it replaces. Sraffa’s argument relies
  on the positivity of rent. However, there is a flaw in his reasoning and a
  failure of the Ricardian dynamics is possible. Post-Sraffian scholars have
  misunderstood that construction and have substituted a static approach for
  it. The critiques they address to Sraffa are better understood by returning
  to Ricardo and Sraffa's own methodology. Fifty years ago, mathematicians
  rediscovered Ricardo's approach independently and worked out a powerful
  algorithm inspired by it.
   Date: 2018–03–14
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:dzy53&r=hpe

12. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Keynes, Public
     Debt and the Complex of Interest Rates
   Aspromourgos, Anthony
  John Maynard Keynes consistently offered qualified endorsement of Abba
  Lerner’s “functional finance” doctrine – the qualifications particularly
  turning on Keynes’s attentiveness to policy management of the psychology of
  the debt market. This article examines Keynes’s understanding of the
  possible influence of public debt on interest rates, from 1930 forward. With
  the multiplier a mechanism whereby debt-financed public investment generates
  matching private saving (net of private investment) plus public saving, it
  becomes possible for Keynes to conclude that increasing public debt need not
  place upward pressure on the level of interest rates, so long as policy can
  successfully manage the psychology of the debt market. This particularly
  concerns long interest rates and hence, the term structure of rates. His
  theory of the term structure enables Keynes’s conviction that policy can
  manage and shape long rates. The conclusion considers also whether Keynes’s
  caution concerning public debt and interest rates retains relevance today.
   Date: 2018–04–04
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:mf2sc&r=hpe

13. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Limits to
     Arbitrage and Interest Rates: A Debate Between Keynes, Hawtrey and Hicks
   BRILLANT, Lucy
  This paper deals with a debate between Hawtrey, Hicks and Keynes concerning
  the capacity of the central bank to influence the short-term and the
  long-term rates of interest. Both Hawtrey and Keynes considered the central
  bank’s ability to influence short-term rates of interest. However, they do
  not put the same emphasis on the study of the long-term rates of interest.
  According to Keynes, long-term rates are influenced by future expected
  short-term rates (1930, 1936), whereas for Hawtrey (1932, 1937, 1938),
  long-term rates are more dependent on the business cycle. Short-term rates
  do not have much effect on long-term rates according to Hawtrey. In 1939,
  Hicks enters the controversy, giving credit to both Hawtrey’s and Keynes’s
  theories, and also introducing limits to the operations of arbitrage. He
  thus presented a nuanced view.
   Date: 2018–04–11
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:7f2yv&r=hpe

14. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Hawtrey,
     Austerity, and the "Treasury View," 1918-25
   mattei, clara
  R. G. Hawtrey was not a man of the backwaters. Through the parallel study of
  Treasury files and Hawtrey's scholarly publications, this work reveals his
  direct influence upon the most commanding minds of the Treasury and the Bank
  of England, the two institutions that, after WWI, shared primary
  responsibility over the British austerity agenda. After the war, Hawtrey
  advocated drastic budgetary and monetary rigor in the name of price
  stabilization. From 1922, Hawtrey admitted the need to decrease the bank
  rate; yet he remained an adamant supporter of the Gold Standard, insisting
  on its maintenance even if it required further monetary revaluation.
  Hawtrey's policy prescriptions stemmed directly from his economic model. The
  "crowding out argument," the centrality of credit and of savings, together
  with the operational priority of technocratic institutions, were essential
  theoretical underpinnings of Hawtrey's agenda: implementing the so-called
  "Treasury view."
   Date: 2018–07–13
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:2rjw9&r=hpe

15. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Sir James
     Steuart on the Origins of Commercial Nations
   Menudo, José M.
  This paper examines James Steuart’s explanation of the emergence of
  commercial nations. Unlike other Scottish thinkers of the time, Steuart
  argues that artifice is necessary for the rise of commercial societies. He
  uses the term “artificial” to refer to a devised process, one that is an
  alternative to the supposedly natural process arising from innate
  propensities. The system of trade and commerce is an “artifice” created by
  merchants to obtain benefits, and established by the sovereign, for his
  ostentation and personal prestige, until it became generalized as a
  commercial nation. Steuart's explanation of the emergence of commercial
  nations accounts for how individuals become dependent on and subordinate to
  the public market. Finally, this paper concludes that Steuart’s Political
  Œconomy promotes a science of the artificial that seeks to understand the
  functioning of non-natural mechanisms and to create instruments that the
  statesman adapts to the needs and objectives of individuals
   Date: 2018–02–09
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:utw9p&r=hpe


17. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Antonio De
     Viti De Marco, the principle of minimum means, and political competition
   Fossati, Amedeo; Montefiori, Marcello
  In contrast to the common maxims for good taxation, De Viti de Marco
  revolutionized public finance studies by placing collective economic
  activity within a theoretical framework, and trying to explain concrete
  fiscal phenomena, such as tax incidence or public debt. The polar cases of
  cooperative and monopolistic states and the state-factor of production are
  usually considered a characteristic of such a framework. Here, we remark
  that De Viti’s theory of the cooperative state appears grounded only on the
  principles of minimum means and of political competition, and on the
  assumption that individual income is a proxy of individual consumption of
  general public services. Thus, it appears that the characteristics might be
  unessential to the real core of his theoretical framework. Moreover, we
  claim that his theoretical framework was not actually applied in his
  explanation of concrete fiscal phenomena. Finally, we remark that he seldom
  employed marginal tools in his Principî.
   Date: 2018–10–03
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:caqu8&r=hpe

18. How Behavioural Economics Relates to Psychology - Some Bibliographic
     Evidence
   Braesemann, Fabian
  Whether behavioural economics has a fundamental influence on economics is
  debated by behavioural and heterodox economists as well as by methodologists
  and historians of economics. At the core of this debate is the question
  whether behavioural economics is shaped by large-scale content imports from
  psychology, or whether these transfers have been too selective to challenge
  dominant approaches in economics. This study contributes to the debate in
  analysing a variety of bibliographic data from the disciplinary boundary
  between economics and psychology. Two datasets from the boundary of
  behavioural economics and psychology are compared to sets of economic and
  psychology publications in quantifying the use of mathematics, the share of
  empirical contributions, the authors’ academic background, and their
  cross-citations via network analysis. In contrast to proposals made by some
  methodologists and behavioural economists, the statistical results confirm
  content transfers from psychology via behavioural economics only to a
  limited extend. The observed level of interaction provides evidence for a
  selective import of specific psychological findings by a small number of
  established investigators in behavioural economics. These findings were then
  intensively debated as divergences from rationality within the growing, but
  econ-centered community of behavioural economists.
   Date: 2018–08–22
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:83jeg&r=hpe

19. Journal of the History of Economic Thought Preprints - Review of
     ​Karl Polanyi: A Life on the Left​
   Schumacher, Reinhard
  A review of Gareth Dale's "Karl Polanyi: A Life on the Left​"
   Date: 2017–11–21
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:nq3mg&r=hpe


21. The transformation of economic analysis at the Federal Reserve during
     the 1960s
   Acosta, Juan; Cherrier, Beatrice
  In this paper, we build on data on Fed officials, oral history repositories
  and hitherto under-researched archival sources to unpack the torturous path
  toward crafting an institutional and intellectual space for postwar economic
  analysis within the Fed. We show that growing attention to new macroeconomic
  research was a reaction to both mounting external criticisms against the
  Fed’s decision-making process and a process internal to the discipline
  whereby institutionalism was displaced by neoclassical theory and
  econometrics. We argue that the rise of the number of PhD economists working
  at the Fed is a symptom rather than a cause of this transformation. Key to
  our story are a handful of economists from the Board of Governor’s Division
  of Research and Statistics (DRS) who paradoxically did not always held a
  PhD, but envisioned their role as going beyond mere data accumulation and
  got involved into large-scale macroeconometric model building. We conclude
  that the divide between PhD and non-PhD economists may not be fully relevant
  to understand both the shift in the type of economics practiced at the Fed
  and the uses of this knowledge in the decision making-process. Equally
  important was the rift between different styles of economic analysis.
   Date: 2018–09–30
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:vdy2z&r=hpe

22. Shortcomings of experimental economics to study human behavior: a
     reanalysis of Cohn et al. 2014, Nature 516, 86–89, ‘‘Business culture and
     dishonesty in the banking industry’’
   Hupé, Jean-Michel
  In the wake of financial scandals, Cohn and collaborators published a
  headline-grabber study in the field of behavioral economics. M.C. Villeval
  (2014) summarized the main message as follows, in News and Views of the
  Nature issue where the Cohn study was published: the “experiment shows that
  although bank employees behave honestly on average, their dishonesty
  increases when they make decisions after having been primed to think about
  their professional identity.” Cohn et al. thus provide evidence that “the
  incentives and the business culture developed in the financial sector may
  undermine the honesty norms of ordinary employees.” This study may have
  important consequences for policy, since, Villeval continues, “it is crucial
  to ensure a business culture of honesty in this industry to restore trust in
  it.” Villeval also argues that “from a scientific perspective, this study
  […] supports the economic theory of social identity […], links this theory
  with the economic analysis of lying behavior [… and] shows how behavioural
  economists can contribute to a broader reflection in science about how
  people manage their 'multiple selves' ”. Here I show that the use of flawed
  statistics methods, yet employed routinely in so-called “evidence-based”
  science, led the authors to distort the “evidence”. I am also using this
  data-set as an interesting example to explore how we can use modeling and
  simulations to provide a fair account of the information and uncertainty
  conveyed by the data, based on Confidence Intervals. I provide the R-code.
  Based on this paper, I question the contribution of behavioral economics to
  the understanding of human behavior and conclude with considerations on
  honesty and science.
   Date: 2018–03–20
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:nt6xk&r=hpe

23. Dobrogea School of Economics
   ARTENE, Alin
  At present, we have all the necessary elements to be able to claim that
  "Dobrogea Economics School in Constanta" really exists in the Romanian and
  European academic landscape. Among these elements, we take into account
  those related to tradition, university education programs, valuable teaching
  staff, material basis, results / scientific visibility, etc. This article
  provides an approach to the establishment and further development of the
  Faculty of Economics at "Ovidius" University of Constanta. The continuous
  development of the collaboration relations with other universities -
  Romanian and foreign -, with governmental or private institutions, with the
  business environment, etc. confirms that today there is a Dobrogean School
  of Economics and, moreover, it has all the chances to last forever.
   Date: 2018–05–15
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:hwn8a&r=hpe

24. What is replication?
   Nosek, Brian A. (University of Virginia); Errington, Timothy M. (Center
    for Open Science)
  Replications are inevitably different from the original studies. How do we
  decide whether something is a replication? The answer shifts the conception
  of replication from a boring, uncreative, housekeeping activity to an
  exciting, generative, vital contributor to research progress.
   Date: 2019–09–10
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:metaar:u4g6t&r=hpe

25. The ordinary business of macroeconometric modeling: working on the
     Fed-MIT-Penn model (1964-1974)
   Cherrier, Beatrice; Backhouse, Roger
  The FMP model exemplifies the Keynesian models later criticized by Lucas,
  Sargent and others as conceptually flawed. For economists in the 1960s such
  models were “big science”, posing organizational as well as theoretical and
  empirical problems. It was part of an even larger industry in which the
  messiness for which such models were later criticized was endorsed as
  providing enabling modelers to be guided by data and as offering the
  flexibility needed to undertake policy analysis and to analyze the
  consequences of events. Practices that critics considered fatal weaknesses,
  such as intercept adjustments or fudging, were what clients were what
  clients paid for as the macroeconometric modeling industry went private.
   Date: 2018–10–15
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:39xkz&r=hpe

26. A Happy Choice: Wellbeing as the Goal of Government
   Frijters, Paul (London School of Economics); Clark, Andrew E. (Paris
    School of Economics); Krekel, Christian (London School of Economics);
    Layard, Richard (London School of Economics)
  In this article, we lay out the basic case for wellbeing as the goal of
  government. We briefly review the history of this idea, which goes back to
  the ancient Greeks and was the acknowledged ideal of the Enlightenment. We
  then discuss possible measures on which a wellbeing orientation could be
  based, emphasising the importance of acknowledging the political agency of
  citizens and thus their own evaluations of their life. We then turn to
  practicalities and consequences: how would one actually set up
  wellbeing-oriented decision-making and what difference should we expect from
  current practice? We end by discussing the current barriers to the adoption
  of wellbeing as the goal of government, both in terms of what we need to
  know more about and where the ideological barriers lay.
   JEL: I3 A10 H10 H83
   Keywords: subjective wellbeing, life satisfaction, public policy,
    political economy, social welfare
   Date: 2019–10
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp12720&r=hpe

27. Produire un fait scientifique: Beveridge et le Comité international
     d'histoire des prix
   Demade, Julien
  This book tells the story of a largely forgotten enterprise: that of the
  International Scientific Committee on Price History. If this endeavour can
  nevertheless still be of interest today, it is not only because failures
  offer insights into social dynamics as well as successes do ; nor is it
  solely because we find, gathered around this failed enquiry, a slew of very
  famous names, and names indeed which one would not expect to stumble upon in
  this context – there is Beveridge and Kautsky, Bloch and Malinowski. First
  and foremost, it is because the object of this enquiry offers a rare
  opportunity to bridge the divide between national scientific traditions as
  well as between disciplines – such as history and economy, or epistemology
  and the sociology of scientific knowledge. Thus, the initially narrow scope
  of this study opens up to a vast field of enquiry, as the object of this
  study shifts to determining how a particular class of objects – those deemed
  scientific – are produced, and how epistemological, theoretical and
  institutional issues interact in this process. Indeed, the conversion of
  past prices (as they appear in the archives) into historical prices taken as
  scientific facts, raises diverse and crucial questions : on the respective
  standing of social and natural sciences, about monetarism, or on the
  transition from the academic field of the Humboldtian scholar to that of big
  science. Viewed through the prism of this particular case, these issues will
  appear in a new light for the simple reason that, in the case at hand,
  fields of enquiry which are ordinarily examined independently are found to
  be tightly interrelated.
   JEL: B15 B16 B23 B25 B31 N01
   Keywords: history of prices;William Beveridge;international scientifique
    committee on price history;Thorold Rogers; Georges d'Avenel;
   Date: 2018
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:97119&r=hpe

28. Theories of the Causes of Poverty
   Brady, David
  There has been a lack of debate between and frameworks for theories of the
  causes of poverty. This essay proposes that most theories of poverty can be
  productively categorized into three broader families of theories:
  behavioral, structural, and political. Behavioral theories concentrate on
  individual behaviors as driven by incentives and culture. Structural
  theories emphasize the demographic and labor market context, which causes
  both behavior and poverty. Political theories contend that power and
  institutions cause policy, which causes poverty, and moderates the
  relationship between behavior and poverty. I review each theory’s arguments,
  contributions and challenges. Further, I explain how to integrate, classify
  studies into, and distinguish between theories. Ultimately, I argue that
  poverty research would benefit from more explicit theory and theoretical
  debate, as well as greater interdisciplinarity and integration between
  studies of the U.S., rich democracies, and developing countries.
   Date: 2018–10–15
 URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:jud53&r=hpe

────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────────
This nep-hpe issue is ©2019 by Erik Thomson. It is provided as is without any
express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in
part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org.
For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at
<[log in to unmask]>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be
rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of
Massey University in New Zealand.

ATOM RSS1 RSS2