----------------- HES POSTING -----------------
Published by EH.NET (June 2003)
Allan H. Meltzer, _A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. I:
1913-51_. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003. xiii + 800 pp.
$75 (hardcover), ISBN: 0-226-51999-6.
Reviewed for EH.NET by John H. Wood, Department of Economics, Wake
Forest University. <[log in to unmask]>
Allan Meltzer has given us a thorough history of the Federal
Reserve's monetary policy from its founding in December 1913 to the
Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord in the spring of 1951. Several
excellent descriptive and critical studies of various parts of this
period of the Fed are available, led by a considerable portion of
Friedman and Schwartz's _Monetary History_. But Meltzer advances our
understanding of the Fed in two respects that that I explore in this
review: First, he considers all the significant episodes of monetary
policy, usually in more detail than can be found elsewhere. This book
must be the starting point for future studies of Federal Reserve
monetary policy, not only for the period covered by the book, but
also for the succeeding fifty years because the Fed's organization
and most of its beliefs and procedures were developed in the earlier
period. The second main contribution is an extension of the first.
Meltzer makes unequalled use of the unpublished minutes,
correspondence, and other internal papers of the Federal Reserve
Board and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. He takes us further
behind the scenes of policymaking.
This review seeks to locate the book in the literature on the Fed, a
task made easier by Meltzer's recognition of previous work and the
absence of radically new interpretations. He supports the positions
that have been associated with monetarist criticisms by Friedman and
Schwartz and his work with Karl Brunner since the 1960s, especially
the Fed's lack of understanding of its role in the economy and its
obsession with financial markets, commercial bank free reserves in
particular. His support is in the form of information about the
ideas, institutions, and personalities behind actions and inactions
that are well known. We are told that the inflation and deflation of
1919-21, the Great Depression of 1929-33, the recession of 1937-38,
and the post-World War II inflation would have been avoided or
greatly moderated if the Fed had make money grow at a constant rate,
as Friedman proposed (1959, 92) or as adjusted for velocity and
inflation as Meltzer proposed (1984). Whether or not we accept these
conclusions, Meltzer enables us to increase our understanding of the
Fed's intentions, or rather the intentions of different parts of an
institution that was at war with itself.
The new material may be the book's most important contribution to
research because it adds to the information available for the study
of the policy preferences of different interests in the Federal
Reserve and their effects on decisions. Internal conflicts often
involved battles for control between the Board in Washington and the
regional Reserve Banks. The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 was vague
about control. The powers of the Fed -- particularly discounting and
open-market operations -- were vested in the Banks under the Board's
supervision. The extent of this supervision -- broad or, as the Banks
complained, amounting to the micro-management of a central bank from
Washington -- was the main source of these conflicts, which spilled
over into policy decisions. It is also possible that policy
differences between the Board and the Banks, especially New York,
were partly due to the knowledge and interests arising from their
political and economic environments. Given the importance attached to
these differences, I would like to have seen more attention paid to
their possible reasons beyond institutional grasps for power. It is
no surprise to find the Board more sympathetic to (or under the thumb
of) the Treasury during the latter's pressures for continued bond
supports after the two world wars. Less expected, perhaps, was the
Board's greater skepticism of market forces. Its preference for
controls over interest rates helped to rationalize its support for
Treasury low-interest programs. But the Board also differed from New
York in believing that controls could control stock speculation in
1928-29 without impinging on "legitimate" credit. Havrilesky
(288-331) found that the Banks' greater reliance on interest rates
continued in the second half of the century. Might those, like the
New York Fed, who are immersed in the financial markets repose more
trust in their operation, specifically in the efficacy of interest
rates as rationing devices, compared with credit controls? On the
other hand, this tack may not be appealing to monetarists who already
find the Fed too sensitive to markets and interest rates. Meltzer
finds that a good deal of the Board's criticism of the New York Bank
after the Crash was motivated more by concern for control than
different perceptions of economic relations (289).
Meltzer confirms the charge that the Fed neglected to develop a
model, or guide, to policy. This neglect can be interpreted with more
sympathy than Meltzer and other critics have shown, although they
recognize the Fed's difficulties, because important conditions
assumed by the Fed's creators quickly disintegrated with war and its
aftermath. They were adrift without a destination, compass, or
anchor. The great inflow of gold caused by European inflations and
other disorders divorced the Fed's actions from the historic central
bank concern for its reserve. The Fed's timid support of credit
during the Great Depression may have been partly due to a desire to
preserve the gold standard (Eichengreen; Meltzer is doubtful, 405),
but its interest in price stability between 1921 and 1929 prevented
it from taking full advantage of its more-than-ample reserves.
We must also realize that prevalent economic models did not imply the
countercyclical policy to which economists were converted a decade
later. An influential theory that implied "liquidation" in depression
stemmed from the belief that deflations are reactions to inflations
that had been driven by speculations in inventories and fixed assets.
These should be allowed to return to normal levels. Deflations must
be allowed to run their course (Hayek; Treasury Secretary Mellon,
discussed by Meltzer, 400). Attempts to force money into paths "where
it was not wanted" merely sow the seeds of future inflation. We can
see where this policy was conducive to long-run price stability under
the gold standard -- price indexes in 1933 still exceeded those of
1914. Even if Meltzer, like Friedman and Schwartz, is right that the
Fed should have tried for constant money growth or at least a stable
price level, the application of such a policy would have required
remarkably prescient theoretical sophistication by a group of
committees of mainly conventional businessmen unused to abstractions.
Irving Fisher was a notable exception in his resistance to
conventional sound money. But his "compensated dollar" plan for
stabilizing the price level by adjusting the price of gold (182) was
ridiculed as "a rubber dollar" (Hoover, 119) and dismissed by the New
York Fed's Benjamin Strong as the work of "extreme quantity
theorists" (Chandler, 203).
Meltzer's criticisms of the Fed, like Friedman and Schwartz's, are
meant to be lessons for policy. In its theoretical and policy
implications, the book is mainstream monetarism, deserving of the
usual plaudits and criticisms: money and output are correlated, so
that money must be important, but no convincing evidence of the
direction of causation is offered.
Prospective buyers should note that the book is not about Federal
Reserve activities that are not directly part of monetary policy.
Check clearing and other parts of the payments system, on which most
Fed employees work, are ignored, and the structure and regulation of
banking receive little attention. The last omission is more the Fed's
than Meltzer's. The Fed recognized the weakness of the banking system
as evidenced by the high failure rate of banks during the 1920s, but
it did not work towards an improvement -- unlike President Hoover
(121-25), who tried unsuccessfully for a system of larger and
stronger banks. When Board Chairman Marriner Eccles (266-69) sought
measures similar to Hoover's in 1936, he was rebuffed by President
Roosevelt. The Fed's lack of attention to the banking structure is
striking in light of England's experience, where the encouragement of
amalgamations after the Panic of 1825, which was attributed to the
fragility of small banks, contributed to the decline in the frequency
and severity of panics as the nineteenth century progressed (none
after 1866). On the other hand, the Fed might have followed Congress
in taking the banking structure as given because the protection of
local banks had been a political condition of the Federal Reserve Act.
Returning to the Fed's model, or lack thereof, Meltzer agrees with
his predecessors that monetary policy was an irregular mix of the
gold standard rules of the game, the real bills doctrine, and a
concern for price stability that seemed important only when inflation
threatened. The place of the real bills doctrine in Fed thinking is
unclear. The Federal Reserve Act has been interpreted as a legal
implementation of the doctrine by its limitation of private
discounting to real bills of exchange, that is, short-term lending
secured by inventories. This had always been regarded as sound
practice for commercial banks, and the Fed favored it in aggregate
because lending for productive purposes was more conducive to
economic activity and price stability than "speculative" lending on
securities. But favoring real bills is not the real bills "doctrine,"
as Meltzer would have it. The doctrine's fallacies had often been
shown, particularly the indeterminacy of the price level when credit
is linked to expected prices (Thornton, 244-59), and monetary policy
(as opposed to rhetoric, for example, Senator Glass; Meltzer, 400)
did not suggest that the Fed believed it. If it had, there would have
been no role for interest rates. In the closest it came to
expressions of policy guides, in the Board's 1923 _Annual Review_ and
statements by Benjamin Strong (Chandler, 188-246), the Fed indicated
less fear of inflation from real bills than other lending. But it
depended on interest rates to rein in excessive borrowing, whatever
the purposes. Whether credit was "excessive" tended to depend on what
was happening to the price level, although this connection was cloudy
in Fed statements at least partly because it did not wish to be held
responsible for price stability. The reasons for the Fed's opposition
to an official goal of price stability probably included its
constraints on the pursuit of other goals, such as the alleviation of
financial stress, and the fact that its proponents in Congress
(especially James Strong of Kansas) were most interested in restoring
agricultural prices to previous heights.
Touching on Meltzer's relations to other controversies: He continues
to differ from Friedman and Schwartz (692) in his argument (with
Brunner, 1968, and agreed by Wicker, 1969, and Wheelock, 1991) that
the Fed's actions during the Great Depression would have been
approximately the same if Benjamin Strong (who died in 1928) had
continued at the helm of the New York Bank. Meltzer believes that
Strong's "attachment" to commercial bank borrowing from the Fed and
free reserves as policy guides continued after 1928, and were
responsible for its failure to increase credit between 1929 and 1933
and its doubling of reserve-requirements ratios in 1936-37. This
position dates at least from the 1960s, when he and Brunner assisted
Congressman Patman's investigation of the Fed that initiated the work
leading to the book under review.
It was a common belief in government and Congress that "international
cooperation," specifically the creation of inflation in the interests
of European currencies (Hoover, 1952, 6-14), interfered with domestic
goals. Meltzer agrees with Hardy (228-32) and Friedman and Schwartz
that the accusation is unsupported. Quoting the latter: "foreign
considerations were seldom important in determining the policies
followed but were cited as additional justification for policies
adopted primarily on domestic grounds when foreign and domestic
considerations happened to coincide" (279).
I do not think that Meltzer's treatment of bank failures during the
Great Depression adequately reflects Wicker's (1996) investigations
that seriously undermine Friedman and Schwartz's interpretations and
suggest that the name "runs" is inappropriate. The three banking
crises of 1930-31 identified by Friedman and Schwartz (and accepted
by Meltzer, 323, 731) involved mostly small banks that were
insolvent. Farm and real estate prices had fallen drastically, and
banks failed because their customers failed. The frequency of
failures in the "crisis periods" was only slightly greater than in
the period as a whole, and were geographically concentrated. None
became national in scope or exerted pressure on, not to say panic in,
the New York money market. The first consisted largely of the
collapse of the Caldwell investment banking firm of Nashville,
Tennessee, which controlled the largest chain of banks in the South
and was heavily invested in real estate. There is no evidence of
contagion. The "crisis" of mid-1931 was concentrated in northern Ohio
and the Chicago suburbs, where small banks had multiplied with the
real estate boom. The crisis of September-October 1931was wider, but
concentrated in Chicago, Pittsburgh, and Philadelphia.
This brings us to Meltzer's (and Friedman and Schwartz's) criticism
of the Fed's failure to apply Bagehot's proposal that the central
bank act as lender of last resort. That is, as holder of the nation's
reserve it should stand ready to supply the cash demanded in times of
panic. Meltzer contends that "Most of the bank failures of 1929 to
1932, and the final collapse in the winter of 1933, could have been
avoided" (729) if the Fed had applied Bagehot's rule. However, as he
(283-91) and Friedman and Schwartz (335-39) recognize elsewhere, the
New York Fed actively assisted the financial markets during and after
the Crash, and withdrew when there was no evidence of panic in New
York, that is, "once borrowing and upward pressure on interest rates"
declined (Meltzer, 288). I find Meltzer convincing when he suggests
that this "was consistent with the Riefler-Burgess [free reserves]
framework," as opposed to Friedman and Schwartz's argument that New
York eventually yielded to the Board's opposition to its open-market
purchases. "The dispute was mainly about procedure, not about
substance," Meltzer (289) argues. "They [the Board] disliked New
York's decision to act alone." It appears to this reviewer that the
Fed's actions as described by Meltzer and Friedman and Schwartz,
generally conformed with Bagehot's advice to relieve illiquidity in
the money market in times of panic. He had not recommended the rescue
of insolvent banks in the hinterlands that did not threaten the money
market. This includes at least the beginnings of the nationwide
closures of 1933 that were precipitated by the Michigan governor's
decision to close the banks in his state to protect them from the
possibility of a run when the failure of Ford's bank in Detroit
(which was also heavily invested in real estate) was announced.
I end with comments that are more differences of emphasis than of
substance: The Fed's irrelevance in planning postwar financial
arrangements is interesting, although Meltzer may exaggerate its
significance. He wrote: "In the 1930s, the Treasury replaced the
Federal Reserve as the principal negotiator on international
financial arrangements" (737). In fact, governments have always,
directly and firmly, controlled monetary arrangements. Their seizures
of the details of monetary policy in the U.S. and U.K. in the early
1930s were remarkable, but the U.S. government's control of changes
in the monetary system as exemplified by the devaluation of 1933,
Bretton Woods in 1944, and the Nixon suspension of 1971 had also been
the practice of Parliament, which decided (with more or less advice
from the Bank of England) suspensions, resumptions, legal tender, and
other trade and financial arrangements. The irrelevance of the Fed in
the negotiation of post-World War II financial agreements was shared
by the Bank of England. Their places in the row behind finance
ministers during negotiations continued an age-old practice. It is
interesting in light of the high visibility of central banks in the
operation of monetary systems that the structures of those systems
belong to governments. Without defending the Fed, which ought to have
behaved better within the framework that it was given, the real
failure to respond to the catastrophe should be laid at the feet of
the government. Herbert Hoover was more active than he is often given
credit for, but he departed from tradition in leaning on the "weak
reed" that was the Federal Reserve (1952, 212; Meltzer, 413).
Meltzer suggests that the Great Depression was not considered a
failure of monetary policy at the time (727). He refers to the
Federal Reserve and economists, and I agree. But this was not true of
the public or of substantial parts of Congress (which he acknowledges
on p. 427). Carter Glass was a powerful defender of the Fed in the
Senate, but the House passed the Goldsborough Bill directing the
Federal Reserve "to take all available steps to raise the present
deflated wholesale commodity level of prices as speedily as possible
to the level existing before the present deflation" by a vote of
289-60 in 1932, before it was watered down into a meaningless
resolution in the Senate. The 72nd Congress (1931-33) introduced more
than fifty bills to increase the money supply, which came closer to
passage as the depression worsened (Krooss, 2662). It would be
difficult to imagine a more damaging commentary on Woodrow Wilson's
idealistic expert (read "remote") institution than Chicago
Congressman A.J. Sabath's question to Chairman Eugene Meyer in 1931:
"Does the board maintain that there is no emergency existing at this
time" (letter entered into the _Congressional Record_, Jan. 19) -- or
a similar lack of sensitivity of legislators in a democracy. The
monetary authority supplanted by the Fed -- the Treasury with an
attentive Congress -- might have done no better. But the sharp
actions in 1865 (when Congress reversed its decision to retire the
greenbacks after voters complained) and 1890 and 1893 (when it
increased and then reduced the monetization of silver during
recession and then gold flight) suggest that it would not have stayed
on the sidelines if it had not been inhibited by (and waiting for)
its expert creation. This is not (necessarily) a plea for free
banking, but at least for monetary authorities that are closer to the
effects of their actions.
I would have liked to see Meltzer subject the Fed's existence to a
little scrutiny, and to consider what kinds of institutions might
have better responded to events or (this is surely an oversight) been
more likely to adopt his preferred policy model. My guess is that he,
Friedman and Schwartz, and most of the rest of the economics
profession share Woodrow Wilson's desire for experts: The Fed should
be independent but use the right model.
References:
Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer. _The Federal Reserve's Attachment
to the Free Reserve Concept_. For Subcommittee on Domestic Finance,
_The Federal Reserve after Fifty Years_. House Committee on Banking
and Currency. Washington, 1965.
Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer. "What Did We Learn from the
Monetary Experience of the United States in the Great Depression?"
_Canadian Journal of Economics_, May 1968.
W. Randolph Burgess. _The Reserve Banks and the Money Market_. New York,
1927.
Lester V. Chandler. _Benjamin Strong, Central Banker_. Washington, 1958.
Marriner Eccles. _Beckoning Frontiers_. New York, 1951.
Barry Eichengreen. _Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great
Depression, 1919-39_. New York, 1992.
Milton Friedman. _A Program for Monetary Stability_. New York, 1959.
Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz. _A Monetary History of the
United States, 1867-1960_. Princeton, 1963.
Charles O. Hardy. _Credit Policies of the Federal Reserve System_.
Washington, 1932.
Thomas Havrilesky. _The Pressures on American Monetary Policy_. Boston,
1993.
Freidrich A. Hayek. _Prices and Production_. London, 1931.
Herbert Hoover. _Memoirs: The Great Contraction, 1929-41_. New York,
1952.
Herman E. Krooss, editor. _Documentary History of Banking and
Currency in the United States_. New York, 1969.
Allan H. Meltzer. "Overview," in Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
_Price Stability and Public Policy_, 1984.
Winfield W. Riefler. _Money Rates and Money Markets in the United
States_. New York, 1930.
Henry Thornton. _An Inquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper
Credit of Great Britain_. London, 1802.
Richard H. Timberlake. _Monetary Policy in the United States: An
Intellectual and Institutional History_. Chicago, 1993.
David C. Wheelock. _The Strategy and Consistency of Federal Reserve
Monetary Policy, 1924-33_. Cambridge, 1991.
Elmus Wicker. "Brunner and Meltzer on Federal Reserve Monetary Policy
during the Great Depression," _Canadian Journal of Economics_, May
1969.
Elmus Wicker. _Banking Panics of the Great Depression_. Cambridge, 1996.
John Wood's main research interest is a history of the ideas and
behavior of British and American central bankers since 1694. Recent
articles include "Bagehot's Lender of Last Resort: A Hollow Hallowed
Tradition," _Independent Review_ (Winter 2003), and "The
Determination of Commercial Bank Reserve Requirements" (with Cara
Lown), _Review of Financial Economics_ (December 2002).
Copyright (c) 2003 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2851;
Fax: 513-529-3308). Published by EH.Net (June 2003). All EH.Net
reviews are archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask]
|