SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Thomas Humphrey <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Wed, 19 Feb 2014 11:59:32 -0500
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (135 lines)
I completely agree with Roger Sandilands.

1. Bank demand deposits are money not credit. Credit consists of loans  
and discounts on the asset side of bank balance sheets. Money consists  
of cash plus demand deposits on the liability side of bank balance  
sheets.

2. Professor Ahiakpor may be right in claiming that cash and only cash  
(that is, gold and silver coin) constituted money of final settlement  
-- true money strictly speaking -- in the first decades of the 19th  
century and earlier. But that no longer is the case. Today demand  
deposits as well as cash constitute money of final settlement.

3. Goods' prices are expressed as dollars-worth of money (demand  
deposits plus cash) paid or exchanged for each good. Such prices and  
their aggregate, the general price level, would exist even in a  
Wicksellian pure credit economy in which money consists entirely of  
demand deposits.

I thought everybody understood as much nowadays. But apparently  
confusion persists. One explanation for this state of affairs may be  
that college courses in Money and Banking (in which the distinction  
between money and credit is correctly identified)  are no longer  
required, or even offered, in the undergraduate economics curriculum  
any more. If so, this is a pity.

Lauchlin Currie was right. Use of the unfortunate and ambiguous word  
"credit" has been the cause of much needless controversy, confusion,  
and misunderstanding. Matters might improve considerably if the word  
were stricken from economics discourse.


On Feb 19, 2014, at 4:17 AM, Roger Sandilands wrote:

> James Akiakpor writes:
>
>
>
> < Somewhere along the line in the late nineteenth century economists  
> began to cite the medium of exchange function as the first  
> identifier of what money is.  They thus started to include  
> instruments of credit, like checks or checkable deposits, in their  
> definition of money.  As Francis A. Walker (1878) writes in  
> objection to that practice, "Money is that which passes from hand to  
> hand in final discharge of debts and full payment for goods...  
> [D]eposits, like every other form of credit, save the use of money;  
> they do not perform the functions of money. Money is what money  
> does." >
>
>
>
> James concludes that "A pure credit system thus does not have money,  
> properly so called."
>
>
>
> But Francis Walker can hardly be held up as the ultimate arbiter of  
> the definition of money as that which is used in hand-to-hand  
> settlement of debts. In a pure credit economy (i.e., one in which  
> debts are settled through transfers of chequable deposit accounts,  
> as in Wicksell's definition of "credit") this "credit" is money just  
> as much as cash would be. (Many "time" deposits are highly liquid,  
> but are not strictly "money" in this sense if they must first be  
> converted into demand deposits before the actual settlement of debts  
> can be made.)
>
> Demand deposits are book-keeping entries expressed in terms of the  
> unit of account such as the dollar. So, as Tom Humphrey rightly  
> implies, they comprise a unit of account every bit as easily and  
> logically as James's hand-to-hand cash money. And they can equally  
> be the means of exchange and aggregated to give us a measure of the  
> money supply.
>
> If the banks extend credit - by making a book-keeping entry in the  
> name of a borrower - unconstrained by any reserve requirement and in  
> excess of any increase in the demand for money (in chequing  
> accounts) as a proportion of real GDP, there will - as in Tom's  
> logic - be inflation. The central bank can then either increase the  
> discount rate or can insist on a positive reserve ratio that would  
> act as a constraint on inflationary credit (money). However, maybe  
> this violates the assumption of a _pure_ credit economy. In reality,  
> however, a bank would presumably be constrained by its capital even  
> if not by mandatory reserve ratios.
>
>
>
> James is correct that a check is an _instrument_ rather than money  
> itself. We know that. But the deposit being transferred by check is  
> money. It is the means of payment and medium of exchange. No cash is  
> being used. And only as and when savings and time deposits (or other  
> financial assets) are actually drawn down and transferred into  
> chequable deposits or cash can purchases be settled. It is in this  
> sense that the quantity theory makes sense. To claim otherwise is to  
> say that an increase in the savings rate is inflationary. An  
> increase in the money supply (cash plus bank deposits actually used  
> to make payments) relative to the demand for money is inflationary.  
> An increase in savings with no increase in the money supply is not.
>
>
>
> This is why there has been so much confusion over whether the  
> central bank should control the supply of money or control "credit"  
> - when "credit" is taken to mean the supply of loans regardless  
> whether this is via newly created money or via an increase in the  
> savings rate [whereby one person refrains from spending as much as  
> before in order to allow someone else potentially to spend her  
> income instead].
>
>
>
> I haven't read Leland Yeager (SEJ 1978) to which James refers re the  
> confusion of money and credit. But if memory serves, Yeager  
> (Atlantic Economic Journal, Dec 1978) on "What are Banks?" insisted  
> that cash plus demand deposits are money and that banks can create a  
> "momentous roundabout process" whereby the quantity theory works  
> through to prices.
>
>
>
> Tom reminds us that Wicksell defined "credit" as chequable demand  
> deposits. Lauchlin Currie, in "The Treatment of Credit in  
> Contemporary Monetary Theory" (JPE 1933) urged that we abandon the  
> word "credit" because it has been defined and used in so many  
> different ways, with sometimes catastrophic policy implications. He  
> showed why the Fed's focus on the control of "credit" in the form of  
> loans (following the real bills doctrine) led it to ignore what was  
> happening to the money supply (cash plus demand deposits), bringing  
> on and then exacerbating the Great Depression. James's posts show  
> why we need to revisit Currie's injunctions and insights - as well  
> as those of Wicksell (whom Currie admired).
>
>
>
> - Roger Sandilands

ATOM RSS1 RSS2