Two points a propos the F grade that James Ahiakpor has awarded me.
1. I cannot remember the last time I ever
saved money by putting cash into a bank. My
university is apparently rather more advanced
than James’s classical institution, since mine
pays me electronically by instructing its bank to
transfer its DD money into my DD. (QED)
2. I have indeed seen Fed figures, and so I
know the money supply has held up (though
velocity obviously hasn't). But my point was that
in the face of a sudden flight by the banks into
liquidity and excess reserves, the money supply
would indeed collapse (as in the 1930s); and I
immediately went on to say that M has held up
today only because of countervailing monetary and
fiscal activism on the part of the authorities,
but that so far the decline in MV has not been reversed.
This brings me to Pat Gunning’s interesting point
about the potential ease with which
liquidationism could be avoided, namely by
abolishing fractional reserve banking in favour
of the 1930s “Chicago 100% plan” which separates
the creation of money (in cash and demand deposit
form) from the lending of money.
I agree. Financial intermediaries would then
handle the nation’s savings separately. Savings
could rise or fall without affecting the money
supply, and if loans go sour there would not be
major systemic crises of the kind we are witnessing today.
I also agree with him that 100% money would
obviate the need for deposit insurance. (In fact
Lauchlin Currie in the 1930s thought the need for
deposit insurance was not the main lesson of the
Great Depression – and nor, for that matter,
should Glass-Steagall have been needed. The main
issue was how best to control the money supply.
That required (a) rejection of the real-bills
doctrine, and the appointment of the best
monetary theorists to the Fed; (ii) greater
powers for the Fed over banks’ reserves, even if
“100% money” was a political non-starter; and
(iii) helping to ensure that the banks were
always “fully loaned up”, and that meant allowing
them a broader range of assets than short-term commercial loans.)
I am not sure of the point Pat is making about
the MV of all our macro textbooks. Under 100%
money there would still be MV – with V calculated
as a simple matter of arithmetic. But
_understanding_ the arithmetic requires thinking
in terms of Marshall’s “k”, and why the community
finds it convenient to hold that particular
fraction of income as money. Currie was not only
the first person -- in 1934 -- to calculate the
US money supply (though not on James’s
definition), but also the first to estimate the
income velocity (he found Fisher’s transactions
version unhelpful and misleading), and was still
developing empirical and theoretical estimates of
the demand for money through to his death in 1993
(see special issue of Journal of Economic Studies 31:3/4 [2004]).
So, to answer Pat’s final question, I do believe
Currie drew the “right” lessons. But yes, there
is also much to glean from Keynes, Hawtrey and
Hume (the ones I mentioned). Keynes mainly for
his early work on money; Hawtrey for the greater
emphasis he continued to place on money in his
cycle theory, while recognizing that in
exceptional circumstances “Keynesian” fiscal
remedies were an essential accompaniment (but
likely inadequate if the deficits were not
monetized); and Hume for the quantity theory. Of
course I could have mentioned others, notably Currie’s mentor Allyn Young.
Roger Sandilands
|