SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Mason Gaffney <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Tue, 20 Jan 2015 11:49:37 -0800
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (248 lines)
The current thread on "Social Darwinism" omits referring to how the term
reversed its meaning for a time during the Progressive Era.  Many
progressives began using it to mean that superior social institutions would
come to prevail over and supersede inferior ones.  By superior social
institutions they meant those more in tune with progressive policies. -
generally the opposite of what Sumner et al. meant.  Discussions are found
in Bannister, R.C.  1979.  Social Darwinism.  Philadelphia:
Temple University Press;  Clements, H.  1983.  Alfred Russel Wallace,
Biologist and Social Reformer.  London: Hutchinson;  Durant, John R.  1979.
"Scientific Naturalism and Social Reform in the Thought of Alfred Russel
Wallace".  British Journal
for the History of Science 12:31 58;  Fichman, M.  1981.  Alfred Russel
Wallace.  Boston: Twayne Publishers; and Gaffney, Mason. 1987.  "Alfred
Russel Wallace."  In Eatwell, John; Peter Newman, and Murray  Milgate (eds.)
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Political Economy  (London: The Macmillan
Press, Ltd.

Mason Gaffney


-----Original Message-----
From: Societies for the History of Economics [mailto:[log in to unmask]] On
Behalf Of Roger Sandilands
Sent: Tuesday, January 20, 2015 10:50 AM
To: [log in to unmask]
Subject: Re: [SHOE] The theoretical divisions of heterodox and orthodox
economics

I’m pleased to see Duncan Foley draw attention to Allyn Young on increasing
returns. But can I appeal to him, when stressing that increasing returns
arise from the non-convexity of individual firms’ production technologies,
to reflect on the significance of Young’s statement in his LSE lectures,
1927-29 (as recorded by Nicholas Kaldor in the Journal of Economic Studies
1990) where he stressed that “large production, not large-scale production,
permits increasing returns.”

In his famous EJ December 1928 paper Young put it thus:
     "...the principal economies which manifest themselves in increasing
returns are the economies of capitalistic or roundabout methods of
production. These economies, again, are largely identical with the economies
of the division of labour in its most important modern forms. In fact, these
economies lie under our eyes, but we may miss them if we try to make of
large-scale production (in the sense of production by large firms or large
industries), as contrasted with large production, any more than an incident
in the general process by which increasing returns are secured and if
accordingly we look too much at the individual firm or even, as I shall
suggest presently, at the individual industry."

The point is that Young wanted to get away from Adam Smith’s focus on
internal economies of scale in the pin factory and the demand for pins.
Instead he stressed that it is the _overall_ size of the market (i.e.,
growth of GDP) that encourages division of labour via increasingly
specialised firms (big and small). The pin factory (or industry) will enjoy
hugely greater productivity if the whole economy is advancing rather than
just the market for pins. And the advance of the economy is enhanced not by
protecting the pin factory from competition so it can increase its size, but
rather by _promoting_ competition and mobility.

Young’s Harvard student Lauchlin Currie (1902-93) understood the point. He
developed a “macroeconomic concept of increasing returns” (HOPE 1997) that
was a classical theory of Youngian endogenous growth that stressed the
importance of real reciprocal demand. Here, growth is itself the main source
of (self-sustaining) growth. It differs greatly from neo-classical
endogenous growth theories that stress firms’ fixed costs and economies of
scale – and end up justifying protectionism.

Young's monetary economics is also important. Duncan Foley mentions Perry
Mehrling's 1997 book on "The Money Interest", but Mehrling & Sandilands
(1999) further bring out the link with growth in "Money and Growth: Selected
papers of Allyn Abbott Young".



- Roger Sandilands

________________________________
From: Societies for the History of Economics [[log in to unmask]] on behalf of
Duncan Foley [[log in to unmask]]
Sent: Tuesday, January 20, 2015 2:20 PM
To: [log in to unmask]
Subject: Re: [SHOE] The theoretical divisions of heterodox and orthodox
economics

A response to the interesting exchange between Ric Holt and Matias Vernengo
on the relation between “heterodox” economics and mainstream thinking.

While economics, like other disciplines, has its own sociology and internal
politics, it seems to me there are some important differences in theoretical
fundamentals between the various branches of heterodox economics, including
Austrian, post-Keynesian, structuralist, and Marxist traditions, and the
marginalism that dominates the mainstream.

One (surely not the only) division arises from whether production
technologies are convex (diminishing returns, which leads to marginal
principles of equilibrium) or non-convext (with positive fixed costs and
increasing returns, which leads to multiple equilibria based on equalities
of average returns). There is strong reason to believe that Adam Smith and
his predecessors based their thinking on increasing returns production
technologies (which provide a robust explanation of the division of labor).

This division leads to different conceptions of money. Specialized producers
with increasing returns technologies are very likely through network
externalities to settle on one universally acceptable medium of exchange,
giving rise to a characteristically monetary economy in which purchase and
sale are distinct. Producers with convex production technologies are less
likely to evolve a highly specialized division of labor dependent on
intensive monetary exchange, and more likely to limit exchange to less
intensive barter. Thus the marginalist traditions either conflate monetary
exchange into equivalence to barter (Ricardo’s “money is a veil”, for
example) or abstract from money altogether in favor of models that determine
relative prices.

Both the Marxist and Keynesian traditions reproduce themselves firmly in the
classical category of monetary economies based on increasing returns
technologies. I am not familiar enough with the Austrian literature on money
to be confident of drawing a similar conclusion in that case, but I think
this issue is important in the Austrian literature.

The sociological “mainstream” of U.S. economics embraced both these starting
points up to about the 1950s. A very important figure in this discussion was
Allyn Young (who is the subject of a penetrating essay by Perry Mehrling in
his book “The Money Interest and the Public Interest”). The flavor of
increasing-returns and a distinctively monetary form of economic interaction
was important for the generation of theorists like James Tobin and Bill
Vickery, who found themselves marginalized in the rational expectations
“revolution” of the 1980s.

One reason “heterodox” thinking reproduces itself despite its “subaltern”
status is the re-discovery by younger thinkers of one or another aspect of
this fundamental division.

Duncan Foley

On Jan 19, 2015, at 6:03 PM, Matias Vernengo
<[log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>> wrote:

Hi Rick:
Don't think I do raise that question really (whether heterodox remained
monolithic; not sure it ever was, indeed), as much as the exam does not seem
to show anything about the changing mainstream. Sure heterodox and
mainstream schools do change. Garegnani famously showed how the notion of
equilibrium changed in the mainstream in the 1970s. As you admit, the exam
shows that Harvard was more pluralistic in the 1950s. That doesn't make it
heterodox. It's a combination of the mainstream of the time (neoclassical
synthesis) with alternative approaches still represented in the faculty. By
the way, besides Ken Galbraith, I would add as interesting and difficult to
classify scholars both Leontief and Gerschenkron, who were also on the
faculty, I believe. By the late 1950s (or early 60s, perhaps), they would
hire Hirschman, other difficult to classify economist. Other interesting
note is that history was required for PhD candidates. All of that seems to
point to a less pluralistic mainstream. Heterodox groups remain, I would
suggest, as divided now as then, and yes some of them did change. Not sure
what's the relevance of that point though.
Best,
Matías

Matías Vernengo
Associate Professor
Bucknell University
________________________________
From: Societies for the History of Economics
[[log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>] on behalf of Ric Holt
[[log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>]
Sent: Monday, January 19, 2015 2:08 PM
To: [log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>
Subject: Re: [SHOE] Answering some questions about the Harvard exam

I think Matias raises, probably inadvertently, an interesting question: Has
heterodoxy remained (and is) monolithic over time or has it changed? One
gets the impression from the post that heterodoxy holds certain universal
characteristics that make it easily discernible over time and if they do not
have those characteristics, then it is not heterodoxy -- that there is a
heterodoxy "standard." -- "modern or any other..."

In regard to Harvard, if one reads the questions carefully they reflect the
interest and research of the faculty of that time. Schumpeter and Joe Bain
had just left, but people like Ed Mason, Arthur Smithies, Ken Galbraith,
Hansen and Harris were there, along with some Austrians I believe. It is
hard for me to put them in the neoclassical synthesis crowd. I find them
more in the institutionalist camp, which I believe reflected more the
mainstream then. But that's just my opinion. Also interesting is that Ken,
in a few letters, defended Hansen's work on secular stagnation and
functional finance (along with Harris) from "mainstream" economists at that
time.

Ric Holt





On Sun, Jan 18, 2015 at 7:14 PM, Matias Vernengo
<[log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>> wrote:
Hi Rick:
Not sure the questions prove that the mainstream is changing. Very fast
read, but these are my impressions. First, most questions seem to be
compatible with the neoclassical synthesis, which was by then the
mainstream, and it might be an outdated version of the mainstream now, but
is certainly not heterodox by modern or any other standard. Further, some
questions seem to discuss old classical (Ricardian) views, and perhaps have
some institutionalist influences. I would guess that Harvard was not
monolithic in 1953 (not all neoclassical synthesis), and there were other
views represented in the department, like Ken Galbraith, which might explain
the broader range of the questions. Unless you're suggesting the questions
display somehow a coherent representation of the mainstream, and that
Harvard provided in this exam a sample of these views. If anything, the exam
seems to suggest that a wider range of approaches might have been acceptable
at Harvard by the early 1950s, and that the mainstream has become less
pluralistic and open to dissent, and institutionalist, Marxists and other
eclectic authors have vanished from mainstream departments, including
Harvard. And that was a 1960/70s phenomenon.
Best,
Matías

Matías Vernengo
Associate Professor
Bucknell University
________________________________
From: Societies for the History of Economics
[[log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>] on behalf of Ric Holt
[[log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>]
Sent: Sunday, January 18, 2015 7:15 PM
To: [log in to unmask]<mailto:[log in to unmask]>
Subject: [SHOE] Answering some questions about the Harvard exam

I have received a number of private e-mails about the Harvard economics exam
that I sent out last week, dated April 29, 1953. Most people wanted to know
if it was an undergraduate or graduate exam. This was the general written
examination for undergraduate students. The exam was for three hours, broken
down into two areas. At the option of the examiner, an oral examination
could be given, "if the mark of the student is in doubt." Requirements for
the economics major in the  early 1950s included: 1) the completion of a
certain number of courses in economics, government and history; 2) To choose
a concentration in a special field of economics and take a number of courses
in that area. There were five major "special fields" the student could
choose from: a) Economic Theory, b) Economic History, c) Money and Finance,
d) Market Organization and Control and e) Labor Economics and Social Reform;
3) To submit a plan of study for general courses, one's special area of
concentration and to participate in the tutorial program; 4) pass the
general written examination in economics at the end of the senior year. For
Honors besides answering more questions on the general exam the student had
to hand in a thesis. What's interesting with the questions is that they
would be considered to be heterodox today, and probably could only be passed
in a heterodox economics department, but at that time they were considered
to be very mainstream questions. This supports my view that the mainstream
is constantly changing -- for the better that's up for interpretation.
Ric Holt

ATOM RSS1 RSS2