SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Ross B. Emmett)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:19:05 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (336 lines)
==================== HES POSTING ======================= 
 
[NOTE: The following is a bibliographic essay commissioned for the 
H-SHGAPE discussion group. SHGAPE is the Society for the History of the 
Gilded Age and Progressive Era (United States). Comments, additional 
references, etc. are welcome. I will send copies of responses to the 
essay's author. -- RBE] 
 
 
        An H-SHGAPE GAPEBIB Essay                          May 11, 1997 
 
                     ECONOMISTS AND REGULATION DURING THE GAPE 
 
                        Werner Troesken, [log in to unmask] 
 
          Many significant regulatory changes occurred during the gilded 
     age and the progressive era (the GAPE).  The federal government passed 
     the Sherman Antitrust Act, the Interstate Commerce Act, and the Food 
     and Drug Act.  State governments created state commissions to regulate 
     utilities, and laws regulating work conditions.   Over the past ten 
     years, economists have written much about these and other GAPE 
     regulations.  In part because of the increasing emphasis on 
     mathematical technique in economics, and in part because of the 
     increasing fragmentation and specialization of all disciplines, these 
     economic writings are outside the purview of many historians.  In this 
     short essay, I review what economists have written about regulation 
     and regulatory change during the GAPE.  I focus on three areas: 
     railroad regulation; antitrust regulation; and public utility 
     regulation. 
 
                       STATE AND FEDERAL RAILROAD REGULATION 
 
          In a widely-cited paper, Thomas Gilligan, William Marshall, and 
     Barry Weingast (1989) argue that the Interstate Commerce Act "was not 
     solely a cartel mechanism for the railroads (as the pure capture view 
     asserts) nor solely a mechanism to correct market abuses by the 
     railroads (as the public interest theory maintains)."   Instead, 
     Gilligan, et. al., offer a multiple interest group interpretation. 
     Analyzing key roll call votes, the authors identify three distinct 
     interest groups: long-haul shippers; short-haul shippers; and the 
     railroads.  Voting patterns suggest that the Interstate Commerce Act 
     benefitted short haul shippers and the railroads at the expense of 
     long haul shippers.  There are also studies that examine how railroad 
     stocks responded to the passage of the act, and key court decisions 
     regarding federal railroad regulation.  Broadly construed, these 
     studies corroborate the multiple interest group story, and indicate 
     that most railroad stocks rose with passage of the Interstate Commerce 
     Act (Prager 1989 and Gilligan, Marshall, and Weingast 1990). 
 
          Keith Poole and Howard Rosenthal argue that Gilligan, et. al., do 
     not adequately consider the role that long-term political coalitions 
     played in shaping the Interstate Commerce Act.  Poole and Rosenthal 
     (1994, pp. 116-17) write: "The need to form legislative majorities 
     gives strong incentives for vote trading. Roll call votes reflect 
     these trades; thus any simple relationship between economic interests 
     on an issue and voting behavior is likely to be obscured, particularly 
     when the vote is likely to be close.  Political parties, even more so 
     in the last half of the nineteenth century than today, are a key 
     vehicle for the trades."  Poole and Rosenthal (1993) find that their 
     variables for long-term coalition formation do a better job predicting 
     voting patterns on the Interstate Commerce Act than do the district- 
     level economic variables employed by Gilligan, et. al. 
 
          Exploring the origins of state regulation, Mark Kanazawa and 
     Roger Noll (1994) analyze voting patterns on an Illinois measure to 
     regulate railroads.  A clear pattern emerges from their analysis. 
     Railroads opposed state regulation, while farmers favored it. 
     However, farmers in regions with only limited railroad service 
     worried that regulation would discourage future development of the 
     rail system in their region.  In short, Kanazawa and Noll find that 
     at the state level, railroad regulation was not a device to facilitate 
     collusion among the railroads, but a device to bring shippers lower 
     rates. 
 
                  THE SHERMAN ACT AND EARLY ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT 
 
          Economists and economic historians find that small business 
     interests played a central role in shaping early antitrust policy. 
     Examining the Congressional debates surrounding the Sherman Antitrust 
     Act, Christopher Grandy (1993) finds that legislators were more 
     concerned with the welfare of producers hurt by the trusts than with 
     the welfare of consumers.  Grandy's paper challenges much earlier work 
     by Robert Bork, who argued that legislators sought to maximize 
     consumer welfare.  In a widely-cited paper, Gary Libecap (1992) argues 
     that the impetus for antitrust, as well as federal meat inspection, 
     came from small meat-packers who were harmed by the more efficient 
     meat-packing trust.  Exploring voting patterns on the Sherman Act and 
     the timing of state antitrust legislation, Donald J. Boudreaux, Thomas 
     J. DiLorenzo and Steven Parker (1995) find support for Libecap's view. 
     Finally, George Stigler (1985) shows that states with an above average 
     share of potential monopolists were less likely to pass a state 
     antitrust law before 1890, than were states with a below average 
     share.  This pattern, according to Stigler, suggests that big business 
     opposed antitrust regulation, while small business favored it. 
 
          One area that has received little attention from economists and 
     economic historians is the role that the trusts played in shaping the 
     nation's first antitrust statute.  Surely the trusts had close ties to 
     the 51st Congress, the Congress that passed the Sherman Act.  One 
     expects that the trusts would have exercised their political power to 
     defeat, or at least, emasculate whatever antitrust legislation 
     emerged.  Subsequent enforcement of the Sherman Act suggests that 
     trusts were at least partially successful.  Also, in an unpublished 
     paper, I present evidence that the trusts, and their political allies 
     in the senate, tried to have Senator Sherman's original antitrust bill 
     sent to the senate judiciary committee, where they hoped the bill 
     would be buried (Troesken 1997). 
 
          There are several studies of the effects of antitrust enforcement 
     and the Sherman Act.  Burns (1977) explores the dissolution of 
     Standard Oil, American Tobacco, and American Snuff in 1911.  He 
     identifies the following pattern in stock prices.  When the market 
     first learned that these trusts were dissolved by the courts, the 
     stock prices of the underlying firms plummeted.  However, when 
     the market learned how the trusts involved responded to these 
     decisions--typically by reorganizing into combinations that were not 
     legally assailable--stock prices recovered to their pre-dissolution 
     levels.  This pattern of depression and recovery suggests that 
     investors believed that court enforcement of the Sherman Act would not 
     reduce the long run profitability of the trusts.  Binder (1988) 
     explores the break-up of the railroad cartels in 1897 (Trans-Missouri) 
     and 1898 (Joint-Traffic).  He finds that the decisions to dissolve the 
     railroad cartels did not even induce large reactions from the stock 
     market on the days they were announced. Railroad rates also appear to 
     have been unaffected by the dissolution of the cartels. 
 
          Significantly, there is evidence that antitrust regulation before 
     the Sherman Act led to similar patterns in stock prices. I call this 
     significant because it suggests that, as passed, the Sherman Antitrust 
     Act did very little to change public policy toward the trusts.  Prior 
     to the passage of the Sherman Act in 1890, several states had already 
     filed suits against the trusts.  Using quo warranto proceedings, state 
     officials tried to revoke the charters of trusts, or of firms in their 
     states who had joined trusts.  In a study of one of these quo warranto 
     suits, I find that the decision to dissolve the Chicago Gas Trust 
     reduced the market value of the firm by a third. However, subsequent 
     efforts to rehabilitate the gas trust into a legally-secure 
     organizational form allowed investors to recoup nearly of these 
     losses.  I also study gas prices in Chicago to see if the dissolution 
     of the trust brought consumers lower prices.  Consistent with the 
     stock market data, dissolving the trust did not affect gas prices 
     (Troesken 1995). 
 
          Implicit in all of the studies cited above is the idea that the 
     trusts circumvented the antitrust prosecutions by changing their 
     organizational form and adopting arrangements that were immune to 
     legal attack.  Comparing Great Britain and the United States, George 
     Bittlingmayer (1985) formalizes this idea.  He finds evidence that the 
     Sherman Act provided some of the impetus for the Great Merger Wave. 
     Unlike the studies cited above, though, Bittlingmayer does not argue 
     that antitrust enforcement was benign.  He argues that it was 
     pernicious.  Exploring the years between 1900 and 1914, Bittlingmayer 
     (1993) presents evidence that periods of unusually stringent antitrust 
     enforcement are correlated with slumps in the stock market and reduced 
     economic output.  The mechanisms through which antitrust regulation 
     could have lowered stock prices and slowed real economic activity are 
     manifold.  But the basic idea is this:  antitrust enforcement caused 
     firms to abandon their chosen, and presumably most efficient, 
     organizational arrangements, leaving them less profitable and less 
     productive. 
 
                             PUBLIC UTILITY REGULATION 
 
          Economists typically draw from one of three perspectives to 
     explain the origins of public utility regulation.  The traditional 
     public interest view is predicated on the idea that public utilities 
     like gas and water were natural monopolies.  According to this view, 
     state utility commissions were designed to solve the problems that 
     stemmed from allowing unfettered competition in markets characterized 
     by natural monopoly:  extended periods of high rates punctuated with 
     brief but intense price wars; and unnecessary duplication of capital 
     (Hovenkamp 1991, pp. 105-24).  A competing private interest or capture 
     theory maintains that utility commissions were created at the behest 
     of utilities hoping to undermine the relatively hostile policies of 
     municipal authorities (Demsetz 1968 and Jarrell 1978). 
 
          The third explanation draws on the long-term or relational 
     contracting literature in economics.  The following example highlights 
     the underlying logic.  To sell gas, a gas company had to invest 
     substantial resources in a system of mains.  The investment was 
     irrevocable.  Once the mains were in the ground, the gas company could 
     not move or sell them.  Strictly speaking, the mains represented an 
     asset specific or non-redeployable investment.  If after the company 
     installed its mains, the city imposed onerous price regulations or 
     taxes, the company was stuck.  It could not move or resell its capital. 
     As a result, before installing its mains, the gas company 
     required assurances that the city would not impose onerous regulations 
     or taxes ex post.  Alternatively, municipal authorities had to grant 
     the gas company the right to use public roads to lay mains.  For the 
     city, this right represented an irrevocable investment.  Once the gas 
     company exercised its right to use public property and install its 
     mains, the city could not meaningfully revoke that right.  If the 
     company's rates or service failed to satisfy the city, the city was 
     stuck.  As a result, before granting this property right, the city 
     demanded a commitment that the utility would not charge excessive 
     rates or provide poor service ex post (Goldberg 1976 and Williamson 
     1985, pp. 327-64). 
 
          According to the relational contracting interpretation, utility 
     industries were never organized as markets.  Non-redeployable 
     investments forced utilities and municipalities to create long-term, 
     binding contracts.  Before state utility regulation, state charters 
     and municipal franchises embodied these contracts and supplanted the 
     market.  The charter and franchise governed the behavior of both the 
     municipality and the utility.  The state charter set strict limits on 
     the city's regulatory authority; the municipal franchise dictated the 
     price and quality of the company's gas.  State utility commissions 
     functioned similarly.  Like state charters, they prevented the city 
     from imposing onerous regulations.  Like municipal franchises, they 
     prevented the gas company from charging high rates.  Hence, the 
     arrival of state regulation represented  more a change in the way 
     cities and utilities contracted than a move from pure and unfettered 
     competition to widespread state intervention.  In a case-study of the 
     Chicago gas industry, I find patterns consistent with the long-term or 
     relational contracting view (Troesken 1996).  Priest (1993) uncovers 
     similar evidence. 
 
                                 CONCLUDING REMARK 
 
          Although I have not drawn any direct parallels between the work 
     of economists and the work of historians, there are several.  I highly 
     recommend the work of Herbert Hovenkamp to anyone interested in 
     exploring such parallels.  (See Hovenkamp 1991 and 1995). 
 
                                    REFERENCES 
 
     Binder, John J.  1988.  "The Sherman Antitrust Act and the Railroad 
     Cartels," JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS, 31:443-68. 
 
     Bittlingmayer, George.  1985.  "Did Antitrust Policy Cause the Great 
     Merger Wave?" JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS, 28:77-111. 
 
     Bittlingmayer, George.  1993.  "The Stock Market and Early Antitrust 
     Enforcement," JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS, 36:1-32. 
 
     Burns, Malcolm.  1977.  "The Competitive Effects of Trust-Busting:  A 
     Portfolio Analysis,"  JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, 1977, 85:717-39; 
 
     Boudreaux Donald J., Thomas J. DiLorenzo, and Steven Parker.  1995. 
     "The Origins of Antitrust:  An Empirical Study," in ANTITRUST IN 
     PUBLIC CHOICE PERSPECTIVE.  Edited by Fred S. McChesney and William F. 
     Shughart III. Chicago:  University of Chicago Press. 
 
     Demsetz, Harold.  1968.  "Why Regulate Utilities?"  JOURNAL OF LAW AND 
     ECONOMICS, 11:55-65. 
 
     Gilligan, Thomas W., William J. Marshall, and Barry R. Weingast. 
     1989. "Regulation and the Theory of Legislative Choice:  The 
     Interstate Commerce Act of 1887," JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS, 32:35- 
     61. 
 
     Gilligan, Thomas W., William J. Marshall, and Barry R. Weingast. 
     1990.  "The Economic Incidence of the Interstate Commerce Act of 1887: 
     A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of the Short-Haul Pricing 
     Constraint," RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS, 21:189-210. 
 
     Goldberg, Victor.  1976.  "Regulation and Administered Contracts," 
     BELL JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT SCIENCE, 7:426-62 
 
     Grandy, Christopher.  1993.  "Original Intent and the Sherman 
     Antitrust Act:  A Re-examination of the Consumer Welfare Hypothesis," 
     JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC HISTORY, 53:359-76. 
 
     Hovenkamp, Herbert.  1991.  ENTERPRISE AND AMERICAN LAW, 
     1836-1937.  Cambridge:  Harvard University Press. 
 
     Hovenkamp, Herbert.  1995.  "Regulation History as Politics or 
     Markets," YALE JOURNAL OF REGULATION, 12:548-50. 
 
     Jarrell, Gregg A.  1978.  "The Demand for State Regulation of the 
     Electric Utility Industry," JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS, 21:269-96. 
 
     Kanazawa, Mark T., and Roger G. Noll.  1994.  "The Origins of State 
     Railroad Regulation:  The Illinois Constitution of 1870," in THE 
     REGULATED ECONOMY:  A HISTORICAL APPROACH  TO POLITICAL ECONOMY. 
     Edited by Claudia Goldin and Gary Libecap.  Chicago:  University of 
     Chicago Press. 
 
     Libecap, Gary D.  1992.  "The Rise of the Chicago Packers and the 
     Origins of Meat Inspection and Antitrust," ECONOMIC INQUIRY, 30:242- 
     62. 
 
     Poole, Keith T., and Howard Rosenthal.  1993.  "The Enduring 
     Nineteenth-Century Battle for Economic Regulation:  The Interstate 
     Commerce Act Revisited," JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS, 36:837-60. 
 
     Poole, Keith T., and Howard Rosenthal.  1994.  "Congress and Railroad 
     Regulation, 1874-1887," in THE REGULATED ECONOMY:  A HISTORICAL 
     APPROACH TO POLITICAL ECONOMY.  Edited by Claudia Goldin and Gary 
     Libecap.  Chicago:  University of Chicago Press. 
 
     Prager, Robin A.  1989.  "Using Stock Price Data to Measure the 
     Effects of Regulation:  the Interstate Commerce Act and the Railroad 
     Industry," RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS, 20:280-90. 
 
     Priest, George.  1993.  "The Origins of Utility Regulation and the 
     'Theories of Regulation Debate,'" JOURNAL OF LAW ECONOMICS, 36(2):289- 
     324. 
 
     Stigler, George J.  1985.  "The Origin of the Sherman Act," JOURNAL OF 
     LEGAL STUDIES, 1985, 14:1-11. 
 
     Troesken, Werner.  1995.  "Antitrust Enforcement before the Sherman 
     Act:  The Break-up of the Chicago Gas Trust Company," EXPLORATIONS IN 
     ECONOMIC HISTORY, 32:109-36. 
 
     Troesken, Werner.  1996.  WHY REGULATE UTILITIES?  THE NEW 
     INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AND THE CHICAGO GAS INDUSTRY, 
     1849-1924.  Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 
 
     Troesken, Werner.  1997.  "Senator Sherman, Standard Oil, and the 
     Battle for Antitrust."  Department of History.  University of 
     Pittsburgh. 
 
     Williamson, Oliver.  1985.  THE ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS OF 
     CAPITALISM.  New York: Free Press. 
 
============ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ============ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 
 
********** 
Humberto Barreto 
Wabash College 
Crawfordsville, IN 47933 
 
e-mail:  [log in to unmask] 
Phone:   (765) 361-6315 
http://www.wabash.edu/depart/economic/barretoh/barretoh.html 
 
"Hatuey le pregunto al padre si iban al cielo cristianos . . . [y] concluyo 
diciendo que no queria ir alla, pues ellos alla iban y estaban . . . y 
entonces lo quemaron." 
Bartolome de las Casas 
 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2