SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Humberto Barreto <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Tue, 15 Jun 2010 10:00:27 -0400
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (128 lines)
------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (June 2010)

Joyce Appleby, _The Relentless Revolution: A History of Capitalism_.
New York: W. W. Norton, 2010. xii + 494 pp. $30 (cloth), ISBN:
978-0-393-06894-8.

Reviewed for EH.NET by Paul M. Hohenberg, Department of Economics,
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute.


Someone who sets out to write a book on a very large subject, in the
present case the economic development of the West and the world since
1600 or so, faces daunting challenges.  Without a predetermined point
of view to serve as a selection device, superficiality is unavoidable.
 Yet trying to force the cussed diversity of the past into too rigid a
format almost guarantees a strained and unbalanced narrative.

Joyce Appleby’s project must surmount additional hurdles.  She is a
distinguished historian and a fine writer, but much of the subject she
has undertaken here lies outside her previous areas of scholarship.
Moreover, compared to most treatments of the same theme by economic
historians, she feels the need to expand in several directions.  To
begin with, she rightly extends the treatment to cover much of the
world in order to keep up with the expansion of Western action and
influence, and the spread of modern economic growth.  Much attention
throughout focuses on the impact of Western development on those,
within the Atlantic realm and beyond it, who paid much of the price --
from slaves, women, factory workers, and people displaced by economic
change, to whole populations and cultures shoved aside or buried under
by the “relentless revolution.”   Conceptually too, the view is
broader than is typical, since Appleby insists on the cultural
determinants of economic change.  Finally, she boldly raises the
banner of Capitalism, notwithstanding that many economic historians
have found the term slippery and troublesome to use as a central
theme.  “Nailing Jell-o to a wall” comes to mind.  Is the essence of
capitalism free markets; secure property rights; individual
enterprise; innovation; capital accumulation; commodifying labor;
openness to change; exchange value as the sole measure of worth?  Of
course, one could go on.

Given all this, one must grant that the book is something of a tour de
force.  The author’s prodigious labors and skill in reading and
writing make it more readable and rich in detail than one would expect
from a work of such scope and of reasonable length.  Nonetheless, I
confess that I found myself reminded, perhaps unfairly, of what Samuel
Johnson said of dancing dogs and lady preachers, namely that even if
it is not done well one is surprised to find it done at all. In this
case, it is done quite well.  Why, then, is my gut reaction not more
positive?

Politics and technology fill many pages, yet Appleby insists that
capitalism is above all a matter of culture.  (I might almost say
“mentalité” although the Annales school remains outside the author’s
ken.) For this reason, she chooses Max Weber over both Adam Smith and
Karl Marx as the prophet of Capitalism.  She situates the decisive
mental turn that produced capitalism in the political upheavals that
swept England between 1640 and the Glorious Revolution.  Having
previously written on English economic thought in this period, she
argues that England emerged from the time of troubles with at least
some share of power in the hands of people who viewed economic
activity as legitimate and not as demeaning or morally suspect.
Furthermore, economic calculation and forward-thinking action had
become relatively pervasive on the part of producers and even of
consumers.  Institutions favorable to economic development grew out of
the changed attitudes, while progress in agriculture and the expansion
of commerce played important supporting roles as necessary conditions
for sustained expansion.

With the industrial revolution underway, the new spirit of inquiry
having hatched scientific discoveries as well as the familiar “wave of
gadgets,” the rest was a matter of diffusion and imitation and of
leapfrogging in later waves of technological change.  Most attention
in the next phase centers on the U.S. and secondarily on Germany.  In
the later nineteenth century, the subject of imperialism gets a good
airing.  As with slave-worked plantation agriculture earlier, Appleby
tries hard to bring the Western land grab in Africa and elsewhere
under the umbrella of capitalism, but to this reader less than
convincingly.  In fact, nineteenth century imperialism, like the wars
of the first half of the twentieth century, owes more to militant
nationalism, in my view, than to capitalism.  The chapter title,
“rulers as capitalists,” is clever but does not add greatly to the
force of the argument.  This is not to deny that the colonial powers
strove to turn a profit from their ventures, but that falls short of
making profit the dominant motive for the last great expansion
overseas.

Appleby manages to devote fully a hundred pages to the period since
the end of fast postwar growth, say from 1973 on.  All the expected
bases are touched, from the emerging economies of Asia to the
explosion in information technology and the recent (current?)
financial crisis.  While many crisp set pieces here (as elsewhere)
enliven the account, Appleby has little new to add, and I would have
wished that the space had been devoted to more detailed and nuanced
treatment of the earlier material, some of which flew by like the near
landscape from a high-speed European train.  A botched reference to J.
de Vries’ industrious revolution, a single dismissive reference to D.
Landes and none to F. Braudel, and almost nothing on pre-factory
industry seems to me to leave out too much.   There is also, in my
view, too great an emphasis on nation states as units of analysis, and
too little on the role of cities and regions.

Perhaps I am underestimating the appeal this book might have for, say,
a history undergraduate or a general reader looking for a survey and
preferring a literate narrative to an account filled with tables and
graphs (there are none).  But for the economic historian, despite
pithy accounts of particular episodes, the stress on the overly
familiar and the inability to engage closely with the hard questions
causes the book to fall a bit short.


Paul Hohenberg, Professor Emeritus of Economics at Rensselaer Polytechnic
Institute, is past president of the Economic History Association.  The
book he co-wrote with Lynn Hollen Lees, _The Making of Urban Europe,
1000-1994_ (Harvard University Press, 1995), recently appeared in a
Chinese edition.

Copyright (c) 2010 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]). Published by EH.Net (June
2010). All EH.Net reviews are archived at
http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW  --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
[log in to unmask]
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review

ATOM RSS1 RSS2