------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (February 2010)
Thomas A. Stapleford, _The Cost of Living in America: A Political
History of Economic Statistics, 1880-2000_. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 2009. xviii + 421 pp. $30 (paperback), ISBN:
978-0-521-71924-7.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Trevon Logan, Department of Economics, Ohio
State University.
Thomas Stapleford of the University of Notre Dame has managed to make
fascinating what is likely one of the most boring parts of economic
theory -- the calculation of price changes. Indeed, standard
textbooks at the undergraduate and graduate level pay little
attention to such issues. He does so by bringing a keen insight into
the analysis -- price indices are not simply economic measures, they
are inherently political measures that reflect the growing interest
of the state in human welfare and economic policy. While economists
know well the theoretical differences between different ways of
measuring price increases (Laspeyres, Paasche, Marshall, and so on),
the development and use of these measures had a more intimate
relationship with political and historical realities than we may
realize. Stapleford's book describes this relationship over the
twentieth century in the United States.
It was quite wise for Stapleford to begin his book's introduction by
considering the controversy around the Boskin Commission's work on
whether or not the CPI was overstating inflation, which briefly
caused the economics profession to reconsider what we knew about
price indices (this is not to say that work had stopped before or
after, but price indices are no longer a "hot" topic in economic
research). As he makes clear, very small changes in the CPI have big
effects (he notes by the early 1950s a 0.5 percent change in the CPI
would cause transfer payment changes of $1 billion). This strategy
highlights the importance and the continuing debate about the proper
measurement of the CPI. Stapleford also uses the introduction as an
opportunity to lay out his main thesis: the idea that rationalization
is the driving force behind the development of economic statistics
(mainly the Consumer Price Index, CPI). To him, rationalization is
the way that the state takes controversial issues and places them in
the hands of bureaucrats behind a wall of objective "science." As an
example, we do not decide to increase or decrease Social Security
payments when we "rationalize" the process by indexing the benefits
to inflation. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) becomes a
collection of experts who use a given technique (supposedly a
"scientific" one) to arrive at a number that has large effects on the
economy. The key, to Stapleford, is to realize that such a decision
is a decidedly political one with seen and unseen causes and consequences.
Overall, this is intellectual and political history of the first
rate. Well researched, carefully argued, it does a good job of
describing the technical difficulties in price indices without losing
focus on the historical narrative. As a scholar of early consumer
expenditure surveys myself, I was particularly impressed with
Stapleford's descriptions in the early chapters of the failed efforts
to combine the state statistical bureaus into a national force with
systematic evidence. While the data collected by the state bureaus
has given economic and social historians a detailed picture of many
aspects of working class life from 1870 to 1910 or so, Stapleford
impressed upon me how much we _lost_ by the inability to regularly
and systematically survey workers, firms, and prices. But Stapleford
ties this failure to politics -- there was simply very little need
for the state bureaus to cooperate because there was no national
consensus for what anyone would even do with the price series that
could be created. Rather, since each state bureau had its own
charge, resource constraints, and politics, the jumbled mass of
surveys reflects the jumbled thinking about the usefulness of
economic statistics at the time.
After these first chapters Stapleford is left to explain how we
constructed and codified the CPI. In the remaining chapters
(especially chapters 3 through 6) he builds his case -- in his
narrative the impetus for the construction and maintenance of federal
economic statistics, and the later canonization of them, took place
from roughly 1910 to 1945. There was no one key event; the needs of
World War I, the increasing concerns about labor disputes and wages
in the 1920s and the Depression each exerted independent forces that
not only caused a much larger federal presence in the economy, but a
much larger federal _measurement_ of the economy. World War I
impressed upon the government (and its citizens) the need for
efficient control of resources that needed to be harnessed for
national defense. In the 1920s, both organized labor and big
business saw the need for standard measures, which were many times
used to settle labor disputes. This is key for Stapleford's
hypothesis of rationalization since both labor and business could
appeal to "objective" measures of the cost of production and
consumption. The final movement was solidified by the Depression,
which left the federal government with the duty to regulate the
economy, and also gave it the power to define how that economy would
be measured. Given the uses of the price measures in the decade
before, it was natural to appeal to these economic statistics when
setting goals and in dispersing transfers.
In Stapleford's narrative the concept of "purchasing power" was a
politically loaded expression of progressives' desires for large
changes in industrial relations, while the economic theorists and
institutionalists argued about whether a "true" cost of living could
be accurately measured. These developments did not take place
independently, as Stapleford shows time and again that the choice of
method and, indeed, the decision to measure at all, were carefully
navigated political processes. Stapleford shows that during FDR's
administration BLS officials used the economic circumstances to place
themselves in a key position for national economic policies. For
example, the Economy Act of 1933 allowed the federal government to
reduce wages by up to 15 percent based on the BLS cost-of-living
index. Stapleford shows that this technique of indexation gave the
BLS a larger role in the macroeconomy as indexation proliferated,
which he argues is consistent with his rationalization
hypothesis. Even after the war the units of measurement they
developed -- the series on prices and wages -- continued to exert
influence after the New Deal policies were abandoned.
While the heart of the book ends at the beginning of the 1950s,
Stapleford spends the last two chapters describing the way that the
CPI came to be used as a macroeconomic measure, and even delineates
the debates about what the index should be. By this Stapleford does
not mean inflation as pi used in macroeconomic models, but for the
way that through the 1970s the federal government more and more began
to index transfers to inflation. This began with poverty lines in
the Great Society, extended to Social Security, and by the early
1980s income tax brackets were indexed. By the end of this
indexation movement roughly 50 percent of federal expenditures became
tied to the CPI either directly or indirectly. While the CPI has
long aimed to be a "constant utility" measure, Stapleford concludes
by noting that while theoretically advantageous, the problems with
the "constant utility" measure of the CPI continue to raise a number
of troubling issues. (Chief among them is whose utility we are
measuring.) Indeed, the BLS has recently begun developing alternative
CPIs for different groups whose utilities may be more dependent on
certain expenditure categories (as in the case of older Americans who
spend more on health care).
There are naturally some drawbacks. One drawback of the book is that
Stapleford paints with a relatively broad brush at times. He
regularly implies that the CPI is intimately related to a host of
other economic statistics, but this is truly a book about the
intellectual history and political history of the CPI. This is not a
critique of the book, but the focus could have been sharper if
Stapleford had tempered his desire to use the CPI history and then
cast a wider, more tenuous net to other measures, especially later in
the book. As economic historians know well, unemployment, industrial
production, and GDP itself are their own stories (and their histories
certainly deserve to be revised or in some cases written as
well). Another drawback is that the intellectual development of the
indices, while covered well for the novice reader, takes a decided
back seat to the politics, but to be fair that is exactly Stapleford's point.
And perhaps putting the economics in the background was a good
idea. About a year ago I was attending a seminar on the misuses of
the Penn World Tables -- the large and well used panel dataset of
country GDP and other macro indicators. The seminar speaker
discussed the fact that revisions of the data changed the results of
many well-cited and influential papers. These included studies of
the effects of assassinations on growth, the relationship between
volatility and growth, and civil conflict and growth. An elder
statesman remarked that economists today do not pay much attention to
issues such as the measurement of prices and inflation, and that we
(as a profession) are worse for it. I agree. For some reason the
thorny issues involved in something as "simple" as a price index have
fallen out of vogue in favor of what we like to think of as "causal"
policy analysis. The bite is that we know, without the use of
instrumental variables and the sometimes fantastic stories that
accompany their use, price index calculations are causally related to
a host of economic issues. Even more, all of our time series or
panel estimates depend, critically, on getting the prices right --
applied microeconomists are not exempted. One can only hope that
Stapleford's book will cause renewed interest into one of the most
important (and _non_-mundane) economic statistics in use.
Trevon D. Logan is an Assistant Professor of Economics at Ohio State
University and a Faculty Research Fellow at the National Bureau of
Economic Research. Recent publications include "Economies of Scale in
the Household: Puzzles and Patterns from the American Past" in
_Economic Inquiry_, "The Transformation of Hunger: Demand for
Calories Past and Present" in the _Journal of Economic History_, and
"Health, Human Capital, and African-American Migration before 1910"
in _Explorations in Economic History_.
Copyright (c) 2010 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]). Published by EH.Net
(February 2010). All EH.Net reviews are archived at
http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
[log in to unmask]
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review
|