------------ EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
Published by EH.NET (December 2005)
Samuel Hollander, _Jean-Baptiste Say and the Classical Canon in
Economics: The British Connection in French Classicism_. New York:
Routledge, 2005. xiii + 322 pp. $150 (cloth), ISBN: 0-415-32338-X.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Maria de F�tima Brand�o, Faculdade de
Economia, Universidade do Porto, Portugal.
_Jean-Baptiste Say and the Classical Canon in Economics_ by Samuel
Hollander (University Professor Emeritus, University of Toronto and
Professor of Economics at the Department of Economics, Ben-Gurion
University), is the latest component of a long-term research project
that began to bear fruit in the early 1970s, with the publication of
_The Economics of Adam Smith_ (1973), followed thereafter by _The
Economics of David Ricardo_ (1979), _The Economics of John Stuart
Mill_ (1985), _Classical Economics_ (1987) and _The Economics of
Thomas Robert Malthus_ (1997). From another perspective, this book
also bears witness to a renewed interest in the work of Jean-Baptiste
Say since the mid-1990s, together with Palmer's _J.-B. Say: An
Economist in Troubled Times_ (1997), Forget's _The Social Economics
of Jean-Baptiste Say_ (1999), Whatmore's _Republicanism and the
French Revolution: An Intellectual History of Jean-Baptiste SayZs
Political Economy_ (2000), the recent reprint of _A Treatise on
Political Economy_ (2001), and the collection of essays
_Jean-Baptiste Say: Nouveaux regards sur son oeuvre_ (2003).
Samuel Hollander's approach in the book under review stems from his
concern with the classical canon in economics. This concern underlies
both the much older argument on the absence of a revolutionary break
between classical and neo-classical economics and the newer one on
the absence "of a paradigmatic clash between the economics of
Jean-Baptiste Say and of David Ricardo" (p. 1). In fact the earlier
emphasis on "the French connection in British classicism" (Hollander
1982), paved the way to the present emphasis on "the British
connection in French classicism" and the recognition of Say's
economics as part and parcel of canonical classicism, considering
"Say's adherence to much of Ricardian theory" (p. 1). The evidence in
favor of a substantive agreement between the representatives of the
British and the French classicism is collected from the careful
reading of Say's major economic works, reviews, articles and
correspondence, and it is presented throughout the text by means of
the transcription of as many excerpts from the original texts in
French and English as are regarded adequate for the purposes of the
argument. Meticulous attention is paid to the changes introduced in
the several editions of the _Trait� d'�conomie politique_ between
1803 and 1826, and to the last statement of Say's economics in the
_Cours complet d'�conomie politique_ of 1828-29.
The Introduction provides a summary view of the author's
interpretation of Ricardo and a review of the literature on the
Ricardo-Say relation. The next four chapters give account of the
evolution of Say's position on value, distribution and growth (2 and
3), on the nature of _riches_ (4), and on the Law of Markets (5).
Chapter 6 offers an overview of Say's adherence to the classical
canon, as regards substantive methodological and doctrinal matters,
mostly in the context provided by the Ricardo-Say-Malthus exchanges.
The Conclusion is reserved to disclaim the general impression of
systemic discord between Say and Ricardo.
As a result of the research undertaken, Hollander's offers a
canonical interpretation of Say's economics, which is made
essentially dependent upon the establishment of the correspondence
between _doctrine of services_ and _cost theory_, the identification
of _riches_ with _utilities_, and the fundamental principle that
aggregate demand is regulated by production. On methodological
grounds, Say's canonical position is built upon his overriding
concern with the establishment of _general principles_, on the basis
of an adequate empirical justification. Say therefore emerges as a
classical theorist on his own and as a net contributor to a line of
scientific inquiry inaugurated by Smith and developed into canon by
Ricardo and the contributions of Malthus and Stuart Mill.
SayZs methodological credentials are convincingly asserted, when his
insistence on a _practical_ political economy is placed in the
context of his strict allegiance to the vision of a political economy
committed to the establishment of a _body of universally valid
principles_, regardless of the circumstances of time and place that
underlay their sound application to the understanding of particular
problems and situations. In the same manner, Say's advocacy of
Bacon's experimental method is placed in the context of his
insistence "upon regarding the building up of general principles as
basis for deductive exercises and the derivation of causal relations"
(p. 234). Moreover, the stance against the Ricardian School is not
regarded as being at variance with the "Ricardian methodological
principle," given the circumstance that Say's "concern was to
establish a proper empirical justification for the axiomatic base and
assure responsible application, not to introduce an alternative
'inductive' method" (p. 248).
Say's doctrinal credentials are also convincingly asserted, as
regards the Law of Markets. Temporal priority over James Mill is
formally ascribed to Say, and he is cleared of the charge that he
"emptied the law of all content by definitional sleights-of-hand" (p.
24). Care is taken to contest Forget's assertion that "Say's
amalgamation of the law [of markets] with his analysis of
entrepreneurship allows us to distinguish his own use of the concept
from that of the classical school" (2003: 60). As proof to the
contrary, reference is made to the tribute paid to Say by Ricardo, on
account of "the _principle_ of the Law of Markets ... whereby
(balanced) growth can proceed at cost-covering prices unchecked by
aggregate-demand constraints" (p. 224, author's emphasis).
Say's doctrinal credentials regarding value and related distribution
and growth issues are painstakingly presented, in order to document
the "substantive identity of Say's doctrine of services and Ricardian
cost theory" (p. 23), with due emphasis being laid on Say's
subscription to the zero-rent, demand-determined extensive margin, to
the inverse wage-profit relation, and to riches as a utility entity
rather than as a value. However, it is precisely in this domain that
Hollander's interpretation of Say's economics is most susceptible to
give rise to critical examination. As a matter of fact, there is a
systemic discord between the appraisal of Say's economics put forward
in this book and the appraisals to be found in most of the relevant
literature. Suffice it to mention the contributions of Steiner (1998,
2003) and Gehrke and Kurz (2001), which stress the disagreement
between Say and Ricardo in matters pertaining to value and
distribution, on account of the role played by demand and supply.
From a different perspective, suffice it to mention the contribution
by Arena (2001), which places Say in the context of a French
classical school that diverges on substantive matters from the
British classical school. In consequence, it is only to be expected
that the publication of _Jean-Baptiste Say and the Classical Canon in
Economics_ will give rise to a debate on HollanderZs canonical
interpretation of Say that is as lively as the one that followed the
presentation of the canonical interpretation of Ricardo in _The
Economics of David Ricardo_.
References:
Arena, R. (2001) "J.-B. Say and the French Liberal School of the
Nineteenth Century: Outside the Canon?" in _Reflections on the
Classical Cannon in Economics_, E.L. Forget and S. Peart (eds.),
London and New York, Routledge, pp. 205-23.
Forget, E.L. (1999) _The Social Economics of Jean-Baptiste Say:
Markets and Virtue_, London, Routledge.
Forget, E.L. (2003) "Jean-Baptiste Say and the Law of Markets:
Entrepreneurial Decision-Making in the Real World" in _Two Hundred
Years of Say's Law_, S. Kates (ed.), Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, pp.
39-66.
Gehrke, C. and H.D. Kurz (2001) "Say and Ricardo on Value
Distribution," _European Journal of the History of Economic Thought_
8 (4), pp. 449-86.
Hollander, S. (1982) "On the Substantive Identity of the Ricardian
and Neo-classical Conceptions of Economic Organization: The French
Connection British Classicism," _Canadian Journal of Economics_ 15
(4), pp. 586-612.
Palmer, R.R. (1997) _J.-B. Say: An Economist in Troubled Times_,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Potier, J.-P and A. Tiran, editors (2003) _Jean-Baptiste Say:
Nouveaux regards sur son oeuvre_, Paris, Economica.
Say, J.-B. (2001) _A Treatise on Political Economy_, with a new
introduction by M. Quddus and S. Rashid, New Brunswick, Transaction
Publishers.
Steiner, P. (1998) "Jean-Baptiste Say: The Entrepreneur, the Free
Trade Doctrine and the Theory of Income Distribution" in _Studies in
the History of French Political Economy: From Bodin to Walras_, G.
Faccarello (ed.), London, Routledge, pp. 196-228.
Steiner, P. (2003) "La th�orie de la production de J.-B. Say/La
production de richesses: les lessons du d�bat avec Ricardo" in
_Jean-Baptiste Say: Nouveaux regards sur son oeuvre_, J.-P. Potier
and A.Tiran (eds.), Paris, Economica, pp.325-60.
Whatmore, R. (2000) _Republicanism and the French Revolution: An
Intellectual History of Jean-Baptiste SayZs Political Economy_,
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Maria de F�tima Brand�o teaches economic history and history of
economic thought at the Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Porto,
Portugal. She co-authored, with Ant�nio Almodovar, "La civilisation
marchande et la discipline �conomique chez Jean-Baptiste Say" (in
Jean-Baptiste Say: Nouveaux regards sur son oeuvre, J.-P. Potier and
A. Tiran (eds.), Paris, Economica, 2003, pp. 127-46) and "On Building
up a Market Society: Lessons from the _Wealth of Nations_ and _The
Great Transformation_" (in _Economic Transition in Historical
Perspective: Lessons from the History of Economics_, C.M.A. Clark and
J. Rosicka (eds.), Aldershot, Ashgate, 2001, pp. 43-62).
Copyright (c) 2005 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be
copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to
the author and the list. For other permission, please contact the
EH.Net Administrator ([log in to unmask]; Telephone: 513-529-2229).
Published by EH.Net (December 2005). All EH.Net reviews are archived
at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.
-------------- FOOTER TO EH.NET BOOK REVIEW --------------
EH.Net-Review mailing list
[log in to unmask]
http://eh.net/mailman/listinfo/eh.net-review
|