==================== HES POSTING =================
EH.NET BOOK REVIEW
Published by EH.NET (January 1999)
Michael C. Carroll. _A Future of Capitalism: The Economic Vision
of Robert Heilbroner_. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1998. ix + 117 pp.
$59.95 (cloth). ISBN: 0-312-17754-2.
Reviewed for EH.NET by Ross B. Emmett, Department of Economics,
Augustana University College. <[log in to unmask]>
A Unified Vision for the Future?
Let me begin with two admissions. First, I would not be a historian
of economics today if it were not for Robert Heilbroner. Encountering
_The Worldly Philosophers_ in my first-year "history of western civ"
course, and then again (with the same professor!) in my fourth-year
"modern intellectual history" course, convinced me that the
"economic mind" was central to modernity. I avidly consumed some
of his other books as an undergraduate student: _The Future as
History_, _The Great Ascent_, _An Inquiry into the Human Prospect_,
_Beyond Boom and Bust_, and _Marxism: For and Against_. Questions
regarding the relation between modernity and economics have
dominated my career since. I thought it somehow fitting that my first
opportunity to hear Heilbroner speak in person came only hours
after I defended my dissertation.
Second, the more I reflect on the questions regarding modernity
and economics that Heilbroner first raised for me, the less my
reflections look like those Heilbroner himself offers. Reading _A
Future of Capitalism_, by Michael Carroll (now teaching at West
Virginia State College), confirmed my suspicions regarding the
central differences. We will get to those differences in due
course, but first, comments about Carroll's treatment of
Heilbroner.
The key to understanding Heilbroner's work, Carroll tells us, is
to construct out of his various works a systematic presentation
of his ideas. This is what Carroll sets out to do. After a basic
intellectual biography, he uses Heilbroner's criticism of
standard economics to set up the key components of Heilbroner's
"system": a hermeneutic, multi-dimensional approach aimed at
uncovering the hidden unifying structure of capitalist society.
Carroll argues that Heilbroner combines Marx's socioanalysis with
a psychoanalytic perspective on human behavior and an economics
focused on how power and social organization intersect in the
material provisioning of humankind (informed by the work of
Adolph Lowe, Heilbroner's friend and colleague at the New
School), in order to reveal the internalized institutions and
values which comprise the capitalist system. Carroll moves freely
among Heilbroner's writings spanning several decades to show how
his analysis focuses on the interlocking nature of, and tensions
among, three central internalized institutions and values in
capitalism: the drive to accumulate capital, the market, and
division between private and public realms.
Once we appreciate Heilbroner's understanding of the underlying
structure of capitalism, Carroll then asks what Heilbroner's view
to the future would be: uncovering the central contradictions of
capitalism allows some tentative conclusions about its further
development. Can the system sustain the drive to accumulate?
Probably not, but capitalism has proven remarkably resilient; it
has the capacity to transform itself even though changes may also
create constraints for the system. The system's real enemies,
therefore, are the disruptions which reveal its endemic self-
contradictions: structural unemployment, for example, which
emerges from the drive to accumulate and the market's organizing
features, yet undermines future productivity, aggregate demand,
and people's hopes for their future. Or globalization, which by
extending the market's organization around the world in the
absence of a global institutional base, jeopardizes the system's
separation of the public and private worlds in the drive to
"accumulate, accumulate, accumulate." In these, and other
disruptions, Heilbroner sees the evolution of capitalism
continuing. The role of an economist like Heilbroner, Carroll
argues, is not to sketch out the particular features of the
future, but to trace "future visions": potential outcomes of the
evolution of the relations among capitalism's central elements.
As you may perhaps see from the previous paragraphs, Carroll's
attempt to uncover the unifying structure of Heilbroner's ideas
parallels Heilbroner's own hermeneutics of capitalism. For the
hermeneuticist, interpreting texts and interpreting societies are
similar problems. Unlike Heilbroner, however, Carroll's stance
toward Heilbroner's system is not critical. He is in fact
enamored with Heilbroner's ideas; and not the kind of affection
Marx had for capitalism! The net result is a book remarkably like
those that appear all too frequently in the history of economic
thought -- studies of little-known or long-forgotten economists
which seek to convince us of their place in the pantheon. Far
more interesting would be a serious effort to seek out the
reasons why Heilbroner's ideas have had such little impact on the
modern economics profession, or to examine the way his work has
been shaped by, and has itself shaped, modernism in the social
sciences.
And make no mistake, Heilbroner is a modernist, despite his
criticism of the type of modernism inherent in 20th century
economics. Heilbroner's modernism appears in the search for the
underlying unity of capitalism, the effort to give it a singular
meaning, and the quest to identify its future. Like Marx before
him, and numerous other hermeneutic scholars of the mid-twentieth
century, Heilbroner searches for unity beneath the fragmentation,
even if only to reveal the nature of the fragmentation.
The hermeneuticist's approach to unity and fragmentation has been
at the center of my attention over the past couple of years, as I
have been engaged in a series of discussions on hermeneutic
theory with a number of my colleagues in other disciplines. One
of the key issues we have identified as a source of division among
us is the difference between those who believe that hermeneutic
theory provides the capacity for creating meaning and unity in
the midst of a fragmented social system, and those who believe
that hermeneutics provides a means of uncovering meaning, unified
or fragmented. The former group identifies the difference between
hermeneutics and science with the distinction between the unity and
the fragmentation of knowledge--despite epistemological claims
for science's unique role in creating knowledge, science
fragments, while hermeneutics unites. (Carroll makes much the same
claim in his chapter on Heilbroner's critique of modern
economics.) The latter group, myself included, identified
hermeneutics with the uncovering of meaning/s, and sees the quest
for unity (in either hermeneutic theory or science) as a peculiar
attribute of modernism. In this latter way of thinking, texts
such as Heilbroner's are the sites of multiple meanings, and
their interpretation may gain more from trying to locate those
different meanings (contextually, or in terms of various
interpretive communities) rather than the quest to render them
coherent and consistent. In a similar fashion, capitalism is
over-determined: a social framework being pulled in various
directions by a host of competing self-contradictions and
tensions; generating multiple meanings and an array of present
realities and future possibilities.
I appreciate hermeneutic theory because it reminds me of things
my training in economics attempted to make me forget, and urges
upon me a humility in regard to the appreciation of the work of
others that modernity encouraged me to ignore. Reading Heilbroner
provided much the same experience. In the end, however, I see no
more reason to look for a unified account of the future of
capitalism than I do a systematic treatment of such a wonderful
writer's lifetime of work.
Ross B. Emmett
John P. Tandberg Associate Professor of Economics
Augustana University College, Camrose, Alberta, Canada
A scholar of American economics during the interwar years, Ross
Emmett has focused on Frank H. Knight and Chicago economics. Two
articles will appear shortly: "The Economist and the
Entrepreneur: Modernist Impulses in Frank H. Knight's Risk,
Uncertainty and Profit," forthcoming in _History of Political
Economy_ (Spring 1999); and "Entrenching Disciplinary
Competence: The Role of General Education and Graduate Study in
Chicago Economics," forthcoming in _From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar
Neoclassicism_, edited by Malcolm Rutherford and Mary Morgan. A two-volume
selection of essays by Frank H. Knight will appear from The
University of Chicago Press in the next year
Copyright (c) 1999 by EH.NET and H-Net. All rights reserved. This
work may be copied for non-profit educational uses if proper credit
is given to the author and the list. For other permission, please contact
the EH.NET Administrator. [[log in to unmask]; Telephone:
513-529-2850; Fax 513-529-3308].
============ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ============
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask]
|