SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Robert Whaples)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:23 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (595 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
 
Project 2000: Significant Works in Twentieth-Century Economic History 
 
Fernand Braudel, _Civilization and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century_, in 3 
volumes, New York: Harper and Row, 1981-84, original editions in French, 
1979. 
 
Review Essay by Alan Heston, Departments of Economics and South Asia 
Regional Studies, University of Pennsylvania. <[log in to unmask]> 
 
 
           Fernand Braudel's _Civilization and Capitalism_ 
 
 
Fernand Braudel is associated with the influential Annales School (La 
nouvelle histoire) that advocated a major break from the dominant 
narrative paradigm of the early twentieth century embracing an approach 
to history integrating the social sciences with a problem-focused 
history.  Braudel is uniformly praised as one of the most influential 
historians of the twentieth century, but a hard act to follow.   Braudel 
immersed himself into masses of materials and emerged with plausible 
broad-brush stories to tell, teaching others how to replicate this 
approach is problematic.  While the Annales School has made only a small 
dent in the economic history curriculum in the United States, it has had 
much more influence on social history worldwide and on economic history 
in France, Europe and the rest of the world.  Rondo Cameron (1989, p. 
406) in speaking of _Civilization and Capitalism_ says, "it contains a 
wealth of factual information, mostly correct, but the brilliance of its 
author's rather idiosyncratic interpretation has been exaggerated by the 
popular press."   Whether one buys the whole quotation, one can 
certainly agree with Cameron that Braudel builds very idiosyncratic 
interpretations based upon a wealth of information, often very 
imaginatively used.  
 
This essay will not pretend to cover the three volumes of _Civilization 
and Capitalism_ but rather touch on some broad themes that have had 
influence on our understanding of world economic history.  These themes 
include Braudel's emphasis on the economic condition of every-man, on a 
global approach to economic and social history, and on the process of 
capitalism and its geographical spread.  This essay will begin with 
Braudel's uses of capitalism, and then take up themes from the volumes 
of _Civilization and Capitalism_.   
 
Before dealing with capitalism, some background on Braudel's career is 
needed.  Many consider _The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in 
the Age of Philip II_ (1966 English translation) published in France in 
1949 as his defining work.  Braudel began this research in 1923 at age 
twenty-one and it was envisaged as his doctoral dissertation and was to 
concentrate on the policies of Philip II in the form of a conventional 
diplomatic history.  Braudel taught secondary school in Algeria from 
1923 to 1932 and then lived in Brazil where he taught at the University 
of Sao Paulo from 1935 to 1937. During this period he kept up with 
developments in Paris including establishment of Annales in 1929 by Marc 
Bloch and Lucien Febvre.   The long gestation period of this impressive 
work undoubtedly had much to do with how different was the final product 
from the original design.  Braudel says that he began to see the sense 
of writing a history of the Mediterranean world in discussions with 
Febvre circa 1927 but that he did not find models upon which to build.  
And then in 1934 he began to find quantitative data on ship arrivals and 
departures, cargoes, prices and other economic data that he felt would 
be the bricks and mortar of an economic and social history of the 
Mediterranean.  By 1939 he had an outline of what he wished to say, but 
he was captured by the Germans in 1940 and was imprisoned for the next 
five years where amazingly he wrote the first draft of _The 
Mediterranean_ totally from memory.  _The Mediterranean_ focuses on the 
history of one world region in a wide-ranging intellectual breakthrough, 
involving the geographic setting, transport and communications, urban 
and hinterland developments, trade, empires and more political themes. 
 
In 1950 his mentor, Lucien Febvre, asked Braudel, who was then teaching 
at the College of Paris, to contribute a volume to a series on world 
history. This series was to feature a volume on "Western Thought and 
Belief, 1400-1800," that Febvre would prepare while  Braudel would focus 
on the development of capitalism over the same period.  Febvre died 
before he could complete his volume.  Braudel succeeded Febvre in 1956 
at the Ecole Pratique des Hautes Etudes where he headed the Sixth 
Section, history.   Braudel took responsibility for preparation of what 
became a three-volume series and was sole editor of the _Annales_ during 
its most influential period.  Braudel published the first volume of 
_Civilization and Capitalism_ in 1967, and it was translated as 
_Capitalism and Material Life, 1400-1800_ in 1973.  Volume II, _Les Jeux 
de l"Echange_ and volume III, _Le Temps du Monde_, were published in 
France in 1979; volume II was translated and published as _The Wheels of 
Commerce_ in 1982 and volume III as _The Perspective of the World_ in 
1984, a year before his death. (When the three-volume set was prepared, 
Volume I,  _Les Structures du Quotidien: Le Possible et L'Impossible_, 
was a substantially rewritten version of the 1967 edition and was 
published in France in 1979.  The English translation, _The Structures 
of Everyday Life: The Limits of the Possible_, was published in 1981.  
That translation followed the form of the original translation, 
_Capitalism and Material Life, 1400 - 1800_, incorporating new materials 
and changes.  In the text, Volume I will be referred to as _Capitalism 
and Material Life_.) 
 
A number of centers that focus on aspects of his work were begun during 
Braudel's lifetime.  Immanuel Wallerstein was instrumental in 
establishing the Fernand Braudel Center at Binghamton University (SUNY) 
in 1976.  Their journal, _Review_, begun in 1977, explores a variety of 
issues relating to the evolution of capitalism, and the study of world 
systems, about which more below.  The Fernand Braudel Institute in Sao 
Paulo is a think tank that has a strong social dimension to its 
studies.  The economic history emerging from these centers is likely to 
emphasize the impact of capitalism on the social structures of society 
and the dependencies involved in the evolution of a worldwide economy 
over the past five hundred years.   
 
                           1. Capitalism 
 
Braudel emphasizes that capitalism is something different from the 
market economy, a distinction that should be kept in mind in 
understanding _Civilization and Capitalism_.  In lectures in 1976, he 
said,  "...despite what is usually said, capitalism does not overlay the 
entire economy and all of working society: it never encompasses both of 
them within one perfect system all its own.  The triptych I have 
described--material life, the market economy, and the capitalist 
economy--is still an amazingly valid explanation, even though capitalism 
today has expanded in scope."  (_-Afterthoughts on Material Civilization 
and Capitalism_, p. 112)  Whether or not one agrees with Braudel, this 
is his explanation of the order of the three volumes moving from the 
lower level of the daily material life of everyman to the market economy 
to the highest level of capitalism.  It is a structure of thinking that 
is rather alien to trends in economic research that seek to explain the 
behavior of households, markets and business firms using similar 
economic models, a point discussed further below. 
 
What is capitalism?  For Wallerstein capitalism is a system built upon 
the international division of labor in which the core of the resulting 
world system prospers, if not at the expense of the others, at least 
relative to others.  A familiar enough theme from the recent Seattle 
World Trade Organization protests.  While Wallerstein took inspiration 
from Braudel, this is not what Braudel means by capitalism.  Braudel 
viewed the capitalist economy as in the above paragraph, namely as 
something above everyday material life and the operation of markets.  
Capitalism takes advantage of high profit opportunities generated by 
linking markets into a world economy.  Braudel distinguishes between 
_the_ world economy and _a_ world economy, a distinction that is not 
felicitous, but as one searches for alternatives, such as "regional 
economy" for a "world economy," it seems better to stay with his 
language.  
 
For Braudel a world economy features a core capitalist city whose 
commercial and financial spread may be well beyond national political 
boundaries.  However, for Braudel there may be several world economies 
operating at the same time, and for each there will be a dominant core 
city.  Capitalism may utilize an international or larger spatial 
division of labor but the hegemony of any particular core city for a 
world economy will wax and wane over time.   Further, Braudel believes 
there have been capitalist worlds from the Italian city states or 
earlier, whereas Wallerstein's analysis relies more on a Marxian 
progression from feudalism to capitalism.  Further, Wallerstein treats 
the political empires like Rome, the Ottomans or the Mughals as 
non-capitalist systems while Braudel would be inclined to see in them 
some capitalistic features.   He says, "...I am personally inclined to 
think that even under the constraints of an oppressive empire with 
little concern for the particular interests of its different 
possessions, a world-economy could, even if rudely handled and closely 
watched, still survive and organize itself, extending significantly 
beyond the imperial frontiers; the Romans traded in the Red Sea and the 
Indian Ocean, the Armenian merchants of Julfa, the suburb of Isfahan, 
spread over almost the entire world; the Indian Banyans went as far as 
Moscow; Chinese merchants frequented all the ports of the East Indies;  
Muscovy established its ascendancy over the mighty periphery of Siberia 
in record time" (_Perspective of the World_, p. 55).  Braudel's position 
would clearly find support in Mancur Olson's work. 
 
One further point on capitalism concerns its origins.  Wallerstein seeks 
the origins of the capitalist world system in the feudal breakdown of 
the agrarian society of Northern Europe in the sixteenth century.  
Braudel is less concerned with questions of origins, but would certainly 
place a European world economy much earlier, perhaps in 
fourteenth-century Italy. Braudel is equally uncomfortable with Max 
Weber and any attempt to tie capitalism to the Protestant reformation 
(see Stanley Engerman's essay in this project).  Again, his first line 
of attack would be to point to all of the developments in the Italian 
city states that long pre-dated Luther and Calvin. 
 
One point deserves further mention, namely the emphasis that Braudel 
gives to the ebb and flow of world economies over time and space.  There 
is an element of Joseph Schumpeter's creative destruction in Braudel's 
view of the process but with a spatial spin.  Schumpeter saw new 
innovations involving new entrepreneurs replacing older businesses along 
with their technologies and labor force.  For Braudel the slowly 
shifting boundaries of world economies have two important 
implications.   First, some areas never become involved with a world 
economy and their economic level remains very low.  And second, some 
areas that were in a world economy, and were perhaps a core city, lose 
their place as boundaries of world economies change over time. 
 
                  2. Capitalism and Material Life 
 
Braudel and the Annales School represented a reaction to traditional 
narrative history with its emphasis on major actors, usually political 
or economic elites.  More problem-oriented social and economic history 
has been mainstream for such a long period that present-day readers are 
unlikely to see anything revolutionary in Braudel's work.  However, in 
Volume I the chapter headings at that time were themselves a statement, 
beginning at the lowest level of economic and social organization. 
 
Braudel begins Volume I of _Civilization and Capitalism_ with a 
discussion of world population during the fifteenth to nineteenth 
centuries, including an evaluation of the reliability of the numbers and 
a description of the balance of peoples around the world.  Beginning his 
study with counting all of humanity, Braudel starts off with a global 
view, involving the rich and the poor, and all regions of the world.  He 
takes on social classifications, like civilized and barbaric, providing 
an overview of global social divisions.  Public health receives major 
emphasis throughout but certainly the importance of the education of 
mothers on the health of children does not find its way into Braudel's 
treatment.   It is a man's world and although his wife, Paule, was an 
important contributor to his research, one has to look hard in Braudel 
for that half of humanity. 
 
Braudel follows population in _Capitalism and Material Life_ with 
chapters on the major categories of consumer expenditure, bread and 
cereals, other foods and drink, and clothing and housing.  These 
chapters, enriched with appropriate illustrations, include the diets of 
the poor, food fashions of the rich, the lack of furnishings of the 
homes of the poor and middle classes, and the increasingly elaborate 
interiors of the more affluent.  The treatment of fashion and necessity 
in clothing is wide ranging.  While much of this is based on the 
research of others, it is an extraordinary synthesis of materials from 
many sources and it is good reading. 
 
The focus on everyday life in _Capitalism and Material Life_ represents 
a concern shaping many areas of study after 1950, a movement from the 
study of elites to those of more ordinary people.  This entered 
archaeology, as excavations moved from the palaces and temples to 
remains of foods, bones, and the dwellings of the poor, or lack 
thereof.  Braudel's emphasis thus fit very well into much Marxian 
history and with a view that capitalism grew at the expense of the lower 
classes.  The following quotation referring to Naples is in his chapter 
Towns and Cities, and is from one of several sketches of cities of the 
era.  It gives the tone of Braudel's treatment of income inequality. 
 
        "Both sordid and beautiful, abjectly poor and very rich, 
certainly gay and lively, Naples counted 400,000, probably 500,000 
inhabitants on the eve of the French Revolution.  It was the fourth town 
in Europe, coming equal with Madrid after London, Paris and Istanbul.  A 
major 
breakthrough after 1695 extended it in the direction of Borgo de Chiaja, 
facing the second bay of Naples (the first being Marinella.) Only the 
rich benefited, as authorization to build outside the walls, granted in 
1717, almost exclusively concerned them. 
        As for the poor, their district stretched out from the vast 
Largo del Castello, where burlesque quarrels over the free distribution 
of 
victuals took place, to the Mercato, their fief, facing the Paludi plain 
that began outside the ramparts.  They were so crowded that their life 
encroached and overflowed on to the streets. … These ragged poor 
numbered at the lowest estimate 100,000 people at the end of the 
century" (Volume I, p. 532). 
 
Here in the midst of a description of impoverishment in Naples we also 
have imbedded an estimate of the homeless as 20 to 25 percent of 
society, a typical quantitative illustration that Braudel uses to great 
effect.  He also tells us that the rich have the political power to live 
in more desirable locations, nothing new there.  It is not surprising 
that Marxist historians would find much to like in Braudel, but there is 
very little ideological in his writings. 
 
In fact, Braudel is much more interested in putting the everyday life of 
all peoples in perspective by comparisons of 1400 to 1800 and to 
contemporary levels of living.  Braudel admired Simon Kuznets' work on 
national income but does not appear familiar with concepts like urban 
versus rural versus national growth rates, and his career predates the 
development of poverty weighted growth rates.  But one senses from his 
discussions of material life that Braudel would have found these 
comfortable constructs with which to work. He also suggests that he 
would have liked to use cliometrics in the analysis of his period but 
that there were not adequate data.  However, Braudel would have probably 
wanted to build up social and national accounts rather than deal with 
behavioral models. 
 
                      3. The Wheels of Commerce 
 
It is curious that Volume I devotes chapters to Money and Towns and 
Cities, which seem much more the subjects of Volume II, _The Wheels of 
Commerce_.   However, Braudel looks at money as an indicator of the 
degree of monetization of societies and the complexity of their 
economies.   And as we have noted, the increase in towns and cities 
during the 1400-1800 period meant an increasing number of poor making 
their material life in urban areas.  On the other hand, this curious 
treatment may only reflect the evolution of _Civilization and 
Capitalism_, in which _Capitalism and Material Life_ was fairly self 
contained and appeared thirteen years earlier than the remaining 
volumes. 
 
_Wheels of Commerce_ moves from markets to capitalism and society.  
Although Braudel does not use the language, he is concerned with the 
development of institutions, ideology and social norms.  He offers a 
justification for employing the term capitalism, noting that it was not 
a term used by Marx, only his followers.  Capitalism for Braudel 
involves not only the use of capital but also its position at the apex 
of material life.  As discussed, it is this aspect of Braudel that has 
had a large influence on those associating the expansion of capitalism 
and world systems as necessarily intertwined. 
         
The first chapter of _Wheels of Commerce_ is called the Instruments of 
Exchange, by which Braudel means the types of markets in which exchange 
took place; it is followed by a chapter on Markets and the Economy.  The 
two may only be separate because together they are the length of an 
average book.  Braudel deals with local commodity markets serving 
surrounding villages and market towns serving their hinterland, as well 
as wholesale and financial markets.   Markets for financial instruments 
including bourses and exchanges, as well as credit institutions like 
banks, are also discussed.  Bourses, after the Hotel des Bourses in 
Bruges where early meetings of merchants took place, also dealt in 
wholesale commodity trade, especially for articles like pepper, cotton, 
tea and the like.  For Europe the 1400-1800 period sees the development 
of exchanges in Amsterdam and London that while subject to bubbles, also 
provided a basis for financial intermediation for even small investors.   
 
In treating the development of markets Braudel gives emphasis to the 
geography of markets, and his treatment is often imaginative, though not 
terribly systematic.  He analyzes the frequency and density of fairs and 
markets in England and France.  He gives more cursory treatments of 
other parts of the world, though both India and China receive their fair 
due.  G. William Skinner's treatment of Chinese market towns and cities 
is discussed in terms of the hexagons of Walter Chrystaller and August 
Losch. Here Braudel argues that the size of the hexagon embracing 
different size market towns varies inversely with the density of 
population (II, pp.118-19).  He then applies this to puzzles in French 
history about the varying boundaries of pays, which he argues may well 
have been due to changing population densities over time--a rather nice 
cross-section, time-series application. 
 
Braudel asks questions about markets that are fundamental but often not 
treated systematically.  When do wholesale markets emerge?  What leads 
to the establishment of year-round shops versus occasional markets and 
fairs? Why did the number of shops proliferate during the 1400-1800 
period?  When are peddlers really agents of wholesalers and when are 
they petty traders?   
 
Braudel concludes that the expansion of markets was stronger in England 
than in France, though he does not probe further into why this may have 
been so.  And he argues in terms of his view of hierarchy, that the 
development of capitalism was interdependent with the expansion of 
exchange.   He also notes that France and particularly China had 
administrations that constrained the expansion in markets and hence the 
amount of capitalistic development.    
 
How do markets relate to each other?  One way they are integrated is 
through the activities of the same firm, most typically in this period, 
an extended family firm.  Braudel examines these connections mainly in 
Europe.  The extended family firm was a common practice of merchants 
from India, China and the Middle East, some of which are discussed by 
Braudel. While he recognizes the importance of business families in 
extending the boundaries of any world economy, this also poses a puzzle 
in some of the diasporas that Philip Curtin has described so well.   
 
For example, in Asia, which in 1400 contained more than half of world 
population, income and wealth, there was an established pattern of trade 
prior to European incursions involving intersections of an East Asian 
world economy that was linked to an Indian world economy stretching from 
Malacca in the Malaysian Peninsula to Calicut and Cambay in Western 
India. This in turn joined with what Braudel terms an Islamic world 
economy extending from the East Coast of Africa through the Arabian 
Peninsula, Egypt, Turkey and Persia.  However, when Vasco da Gama 
arrived in Calicut in 1498, it was not the core city of an Indian world 
economy, nor is it obvious that there was such a core city.  Vijayanagar 
was a major South Indian empire at this time but its ability to expand 
northward was constrained by the presence of the five hostile Bahami 
kingdoms.  The Mughal empire only emerges after 1526.  Calicut is itself 
ruled by the Zamorin, a Hindu ruler whose state was physically quite 
small, and who did not have territorial ambitions.  As Braudel notes, 
the proportion of Arabs, Indian Muslims, Hindus, and Chinese among the 
actual merchant groups and shippers varied over the centuries.  
Diasporas like Malacca and Calicut were home or branch office to Arabs, 
Armenians, Chinese, Hindus, Bohras, Khojas and similar Muslim groups, 
Jews, Malays and others.  The activities of these traders seem to fit 
Braudel's model of high profit seekers linking smaller markets.  
However, the claim that these Asian world economies of the fifteenth and 
earlier centuries involved core cities seems strained.  Even after the 
Mughal, Ming, Ottoman and Persian empires were established, it is 
problematic. 
 
The remaining chapters of _Wheels of Commerce_ deal with the development 
of capitalism and the role of the state in markets and in establishing 
monopolies including a lengthy treatment of the activities of the 
merchant trading monopolies in Africa, Asia and the Americas.  Braudel's 
treatment of society is a wide-ranging social and political analysis 
including discussions of hierarchies, revolts and the state and social 
order.  Braudel does not use the terminology, "social norms," but in a 
section "Civilizations do not always put up a fight" (II, p. 555) he 
certainly explores their importance.  He says, "When Europe came to life 
again in the eleventh century, the market economy and monetary 
sophistication were 'scandalous' novelties. Civilization, standing for 
ancient tradition, was by definition hostile to innovation.  So it said 
no to the market, no to profit making, no to capital.  At best it was 
suspicious and reticent.  Then as the years passed, the demands and 
pressures of everyday life became more urgent.  European civilization 
was caught in a permanent conflict that was pulling it apart.  So with a 
bad grace, it allowed change to force the gates.  And the experience was 
not peculiar to the West."  
 
                    4. The Perspective of the World 
 
In his very ambitious last volume, Braudel deals with long cycles, the 
emergence of various world economies, historical problems in measuring 
GDP per person, the colonial economies and the industrial revolution.  
It is certainly successful in one of its aims, to treat the economic 
history of the 1400-1800 period as a story of the world, not simply 
Western Europe.  There are rich discussions of Africa, the Americas, and 
Asia balancing well the perspective of the colonizer and the colonized.  
In his essay on Max Weber, Engerman (p. 5) places Weber and Braudel, 
along with David Landes, Joel Mokyr, Douglass North, Nathan Rosenberg 
and others as scholars dealing with the "perceived uniqueness of the 
Western European economy."  Let me close this essay by arguing that 
while Braudel has a lot to say about developments in Western Europe, he 
did not see a simple explanation of the causes of growth in the West, 
nor did he think this was the most interesting question to explore. 
 
The uniqueness of Western European experience has certainly been taken 
as the phenomenon to be explained by many economic historians.  Writers 
like Weber not only looked at European evidence in the Protestant 
Reformation but also offered explanations of why the religions of other 
societies, such as India, were less conducive to growth.  Braudel is not 
at home with Weber, nor does he seem to give great importance to 
institutions like private property, contract, and the like. In fact, he 
does not seem to accept even the premise that there is something unique 
to be explained about the development of capitalism in Europe. 
 
It might be argued that this is because of Braudel's idiosyncratic view 
of capitalism.  Let me again quote Braudel;   
 
        "Throughout this book, I have argued that capitalism has been 
potentially visible since the dawn of history, and that it has developed 
and perpetuated itself down the ages. (III, p. 620) ... It would however 
be a mistake to imagine capitalism as something that developed in a 
series of stages or leaps--from mercantile capitalism to industrial 
capitalism to finance capitalism, with some kind of regular progression 
from one phase to the next, with 'true' capitalism appearing only at the 
late stage when it took over production, and the only permissible term 
for the early period being mercantile capitalism or even 
'pre-capitalism'.  In fact as we have seen, the great 'merchants' of the 
past never specialized: they went in indiscriminately, simultaneously or 
successively, for trade, banking, finance, speculation on the Stock 
Exchange, 'industrial' production, whether under the putting-out system 
or more rarely in manufactories.  The whole panoply of forms of 
capitalism--commercial, industrial, banking--was already employed in 
thirteenth century Florence, in seventeenth-century Amsterdam, in London 
before the eighteenth century"(III, p. 621). 
 
Here Braudel strongly sees in his period and earlier the same business 
forms that exist today and to which others attribute the uniqueness of 
Western European experience.   
 
However, the following quotation perhaps illustrates where Braudel 
imparts his own special view of capitalism.  He says,    
 
        "The worst error of all is to suppose that capitalism is simply 
an 
'economic system,' whereas in fact it lives off the social order, 
standing almost on a footing with the state, whether as adversary or 
accomplice: it is and always has been a massive force, filling the 
horizon.  Capitalism also benefits from all the support that culture 
provides for the solidity of the social edifice, for culture--though 
unequally distributed and shot through with contradictory currents--does 
in the end contribute the best of itself to propping up the existing 
order.  And lastly capitalism can count on the dominant classes who, 
when they defend it, are defending themselves. 
        Of the various social hierarchies--the hierarchies of wealth, of 
state power or of culture, that oppose yet support each other--which is 
the most important?  The answer as we have already seen, is that it may 
depend on the time, the place and who is speaking" (III, p. 623). 
 
Braudel has a number of elements of Schumpeter in his view of world 
economic history, in particular long cycles and creative destruction.  
One of his important insights shared by many others who stress uneven or 
unbalanced growth is that world economies have changing borders and that 
there are often areas not included in any world economy.  Indian 
software programmers are writing for Oracle in Bangalore while other 
areas of India (and many other world areas) are as yet unaffected by the 
information technology revolution.  Most large countries have special 
development programs for backward areas, of which many have had 
flourishing histories, such as natural resource-rich Bihar and Eastern 
Uttar Pradesh in India, the seat of the Mauryan Empire and the 
birthplace of the Buddha. 
 
However, Braudel departs sharply from Schumpeter in how he views the 
capitalist entrepreneur.  For Braudel the monopolistic character of 
capitalism is the key element of privilege and the link between the 
state and society.  He says, 
 
        "The rise of capitalism in the nineteenth century has been 
described, even by Marx, even by Lenin, as eminently, indeed healthily 
competitive.  Were such observers influenced by illusions, inherited 
assumptions, ancient errors of judgement?  In the eighteenth century, 
compared to the unearned privileges of a 'leisured' aristocracy, the 
privileges of merchants may perhaps have looked like a fair reward for 
labour; in the nineteenth century, after the age of the big companies 
and their state monopolies (the Indies companies for instance) the mere 
freedom of trading may have seemed the equivalent of competition.  And 
industrial production (which was however only one sector of capitalism) 
was still quite frequently handled by small firms which did indeed 
compete on the market and continue to do so today.  Hence the classic 
image of the entrepreneur serving the public interest, which persisted 
throughout the nineteenth century, while the virtues of laissez-faire 
and free trade were everywhere celebrated. 
        The extraordinary thing is that such images should still be with 
us today in the language spoken by politicians and journalists, in works 
of popularization and in the teaching of economics, when doubt long ago 
entered the minds of the specialists..."(III, pp. 628-9). 
 
These closing quotations from Braudel restate his view that everyday 
material life and operation of markets proceed at one level while 
capitalism carries on at a higher level above the others.  Further 
Braudel sees capitalism as closely related to the political elites of 
the world economy in which they are operating.  While Braudel's view of 
the world economy is shared by many Marxist historians it is also 
consistent with the writers like John Kenneth Galbraith and Mancur 
Olsen, with whom I sense more affinity. 
  
                           5. Conclusion 
 
One cannot write an economic history of the world of the last five 
hundred years and not at least list Fernand Braudel in your 
bibliography.  But how well does Braudel stand up today? My answer would 
be very well indeed at several levels.  Landes (1998, xvii) introduces 
his recent book with an account of the inability of contemporary 
medicine in 1836 to save Nathan Rothschild, the richest person in the 
world at the time, from death by blood poisoning.  Braudel put medical 
advances and public health practices up front in _Capitalism and 
Material Life_ as critical to the improvements in economic well being of 
the world in the early modern period, clearly a theme shared with Landes 
and many others.  He likewise saw the importance of historical 
demography to our understanding of development of the global economy. 
 
Related to these demographic themes is Braudel's concern with how health 
and material well being were distributed.  He saw the great inequalities 
generated in world economies, and thought it important to describe 
them.  He documents inequalities in both the distribution of private and 
public goods and services and sees systems of privilege as part of past 
and present economies.  And while he would have liked a more equitable 
world, this is not a major theme in _Capitalism and Civilization_.  A 
major theme that has contemporary resonance is the uneven development of 
different geographic regions of the world, and the lack of convergence 
of world economies, and more particularly the persistence of regions 
that have never been part of a world economy, or were part of a world 
economy in the past, but not at present. 
 
Braudel's distinction between markets and capitalism is probably least 
likely to make it into mainstream economic history, yet in many ways it 
also has a very contemporary ring as we move towards becoming one world 
economy.  It is not hard to imagine Braudel finding analogies in this 
period for phenomena like "not in my backyard" or the internet.  In 
today's world of mega-mergers that need support by one or more nation 
states, of Airbus-Boeing battles and of Microsoft anti-trust actions, 
the Braudel perspective of the world fits surprisingly well.  The 
importance of being first when there are declining costs, learning by 
doing, or other scale factors that provide barriers to entry into 
markets are not foreign to the world that Braudel describes.  Often, as 
in the case of the trading companies, monopoly was based upon government 
support as in the cable industry today, and much of the capitalism that 
Braudel describes is related to retaining government support or 
preventing government interference. 
 
 
References:  
 
Braudel, Fernand. 1966 (English translation, 1972-73). _The 
Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II_. New 
York: Harper and Row. 
  
Braudel, Fernand.  1977. _Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and 
Capitalism_.  Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.  
 
Cameron, Rondo. 1991. _Economic History of the World_. New York: Oxford 
University Press. 
 
Curtin, Philip. 1984. _Cross-Cultural Trade in World History_. London: 
Cambridge University Press. 
 
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1967. _The New Industrial State_. Boston: 
Houghton-Mifflin. 
 
Landes, David  S. 1998. _The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are 
So Rich and Some So Poor_. New York: W.W. Norton. 
 
Olson, Mancur. 2000. _Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and 
Capitalist Dictatorships_. New York: Basic Books. 
 
Schumpeter, Joseph. 1942. _Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy_ . New 
York: Harper and Brothers. 
 
 
Copyright (c) 2000 by EH.NET. All rights reserved.  For permissions, 
please contact the EH.NET Administrator ([log in to unmask]; 
Telephone: 513-529-2850; Fax: 513-529-3308) 
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2