SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
[log in to unmask] (Pat Gunning)
Date:
Fri Mar 31 17:18:19 2006
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (108 lines)
----------------- HES POSTING ----------------- 
 
In response to James Ahiakpor: 
 
As to the question of Keynes's monetary theory (James mentioned  
savings rates, interest, and investment), one might want to note the  
existence of a German version of Mises Theory of Money and Credit  
(1913), which was available during the Hayek-Keynes debates. Keynes  
wrote a review of that book but later admitted that he did not  
understand German well enough to be able to comprehend new  
arguments in that language. Apparently, Keynes and many of his  
followers did not understand that book. Many of Hayek's critiques of  
Keynes's monetary theory are based on reasoning that is present in that  
book. Incidentally, it should be noted that the Hayek-Keynes debates  
were about Keynes's book on money, not his General Theory, and that  
Keynes claimed after the debates that he had changed many of the  
views expressed in the Money book anyway. So there was no Hayek- 
Keynes debate about the General Theory. The Hayek-based critiques  
of the General Theory came largely from his students. Henry Hazlitt  
(1960) collected a number of such critiques.   
 
Regarding the concept of aggregate demand and the macroeconomics  
based on it, it appears, James, that your message is a kind of bait to the  
Austrians. I'll take the bait, although the term "Austrian economics"  
today refers to an eclectic group and I am not sure whether I would fit  
into it.   
 
The question raised by macroeconomics, based on the concept of  
aggregate demand, is whether economics ought to be applied statistics  
or a theory of action, or choice. In my view, no one can competently  
interpret aggregate statistics without a detailed image, or model, of  
action or choice. If this is true, an argument against a macroeconomics  
that is based on aggregate demand is that it has diverted the attention of  
many great minds away from the theory of action and toward the  
analysis of the statistic relationships among aggregates. It has helped to  
promote what Hayek in his Nobel lecture called a "pretense of  
knowledge."   
 
The problem with Keynes's interpretation of Say's law was that he  
disconnected the theory of statistical aggregates from the choice of  
_each_ of the actors. For example, his theory of the cycle focused  
only on a particular class of actors, the speculators, thereby ignoring  
the detailed investigation of the "supply-creates-its-own-demand"  
actions in the market economy (i.e., ignoring the the propensity to  
"truck, barter, and exchange"). The question raised by a deep and  
prolonged cycle in an unrestricted economy is why money does not  
perform its function of facilitating trade among the separate specialists  
in a modern capitalist system. By focussing on speculation, Keynes  
ignored the demand by traders for a form of money that will enable  
them to trade. Thus they were not led to ask "what the governments  
had done to our money."   
 
We must presume that the separate individual actions of the numerous  
specialists in a market economy is imaginative, inventive, and largely  
beyond the purview of a single economist or a single model. Hayek's  
1937 and 1945 papers on knowledge give one the kind of  
understanding of specialization that leads to this hypothesis. The study  
of statistical aggregates does not. It tempts one to think that he has  
answers to economic problems. The best example of this today is in  
growth theory, where people unceasingly try to build mathematical  
models of human activities that are impossible to quantify. Because a  
statistical relationship of the past (for example the "consumption  
function)" has been discovered, the macroeconomist of this type thinks  
that he has reason to believe that this relationship will exist in the 
future  
and that, because it will, he can not only predict the effects of a broad- 
based policy but that those effects will occur if the policy is adopted.  
The self-assured, even arrogant, Keynesian policy maker -- who  
disregards (1) the complexity of individual decisions and their  
relationship, (2) the fact that statistical data is always data from the  
past, and (3) that policy in a democracy requires consensus -- is born.   
 
This was the kind of crass Keynesianism that was being taught in the  
early macro textbooks and that is still taught in some measure today.   
 
The answer to Greg's question about why these obviously false ideas  
persist is that the models give students and professors what they want -- 
 the belief that understanding the market economy is a simple process  
of working out a mathematical model. The textbooks not only nurture  
this view; they rely on it as a selling point. It sells because teachers 
find  
it worthwhile to give students the impression that by reading the  
material, they will learn, with a minimum of work, to understand and  
control the economy. Moreover, because there is no end to the  
complexity of mathematical models, the mathematical approach helps  
separate the teachers from the students and to create a demand for  
more sophisticated models that only the teachers can satisfy.   
 
Hazlitt, Henry (ed.), The Critics of Keynesian Economics, Lanham,  
Maryland: University Press of America, 1983. (originally published in  
1960)   
 
Hayek, F. A. (1937). "Economics and Knowledge." Economica:  
February. Reprinted in F. A. Hayek (1948). Individualism and  
Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.   
 
Hayek, F. A. (1945). "The Use of Knowledge in Society." American  
Economic Review. 35 (4): 519-30.   
 
von Mises, Ludwig (1935). The Theory of Money and Credit. New  
York: Harcourt Brace. (originally published in German in 1912).   
 
Pat Gunning, Sultan Qaboos University, Oman 
 
------------ FOOTER TO HES POSTING ------------ 
For information, send the message "info HES" to [log in to unmask] 
 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2