SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show HTML Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Łukasz Hardt <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Thu, 29 Nov 2012 20:04:44 +0100
Content-Type:
multipart/alternative
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (11 kB) , text/html (17 kB)
Dear All,

 

I am searching for a book focusing on the history of economic growth
theories. Any suggestions?

 

Regards and thanks in advance,

Lukasz Hardt

Dep. of Economics,

University of Warsaw, Poland

 

 

 

From: Societies for the History of Economics [mailto:[log in to unmask]] On
Behalf Of Humberto Barreto
Sent: Thursday, November 29, 2012 9:44 AM
To: [log in to unmask]
Subject: [SHOE] RVW -- Eloranta on Jonasson and Hyttinen, eds, _Anticipating
The Wealth of Nations: The Selected Works of Anders Chydenius (1729-1803)_

 

Title: Anticipating The Wealth of Nations: The Selected Works of Anders
Chydenius (1729-1803)

Published by EH.Net (November 2012)

Maren Jonasson and Pertti Hyttinen, editors, Anticipating The Wealth of
Nations: The Selected Works of Anders Chydenius (1729-1803). Translated from
the original by Peter C. Hogg. London: Routledge, 2012. xxv + 382 pp. $130
(hardcover), ISBN: 978-0-415-55133-5.

Reviewed for EH.Net by Jari Eloranta, Department of History, Appalachian
State University.

"Freedom never exists without causing us to desire it once we know of it:
our desires guide us in all our actions" (Anders Chydenius, 1763, p. 101 in
this volume)

Anticipating The Wealth of Nations is a collection of the most important
writings of Anders Chydenius, eleven texts in total, while a full
five-volume set of his complete works (about 85 texts in total) will be
published in the coming years in Finnish and Swedish (and later online). Who
was Anders Chydenius? He was an eighteenth-century Finnish-Swedish
clergyman, writer, and political philosopher, whose ideas are often compared
to those of Adam Smith. The texts are aligned with some of his key
interests, such as Swedish politics of the time, freedom of information,
occupation, and religion, as well as broader economic issues of the time.
Moreover, the book features an excellent introduction by one of the best
known Nordic economic historians, Lars Magnusson. Each of the original texts
is followed by a brief commentary by him as well.

As Magnusson points out in the introduction, Chydenius is often, unfairly
so, solely compared to Adam Smith and his monumental achievement, An Inquiry
into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776), especially since
Chydenius' writings preceded Smith's. In fact, both were influenced by
eighteenth-century economic and political thought, for example the French
Physiocrats, with Chydenius more so than Smith. There are many similar
themes in their writings, ranging from ideas about freedom of thought and
liberty to more practical economic issues and policies. However, as a whole,
Chydenius' writings are less theoretical by nature and perhaps also a bit
more practical as policy statements. 

This review can only scratch the surface of these works, presenting some
examples of the economic ideas in the writings (especially the text called
The National Gain). For a fuller picture, I urge all scholars of the history
of economic thought to peruse the book on their own. Moreover, I will not go
into great detail about the life and personal history of Chydenius, beyond a
brief biography, since that is also not the main contribution of this
volume.

Anders Chydenius was born in 1729 in Sotkamo, Finland, to a middle-class
family, as his father was the rector of a large parish in Northern Finland.
Anders also became very accustomed to a rural lifestyle; something that
profoundly influenced his worldview in later life. Finland at the time was a
part of Sweden, a state of affairs that had lasted for over 500 years. This
was also the heyday of mercantilism, an ideology aimed at maximizing exports
over imports and emphasizing the state's control over economic affairs in
the realm. In this case that meant that all foreign trade had to go through
the so-called staple towns, and Finland only had a few of those in the south
and Northern Finland had none until 1765. This was often perceived to be an
unjust system in the more peripheral parts of the nation, and certainly
influenced Chydenius' thinking on economic policy, up until his death in
1803.

Politics became a natural outlet for Chydenius after his university studies.
Eighteenth century Sweden was a fertile ground for ideological debates,
given the expansion of the universities and the more flexible ideas about
democracy, not to mention the intense competition between the two main
political parties (the so-called Hats and Caps). University life exposed him
to new and radical ideas, and he concentrated on the study of philosophy and
religion. Ultimately this led to his selection of profession and employment
as a preacher, initially under his father's supervision, and later his own
appointment as a chaplain and finally the rector of a parish.

Anders became fluent in both Finnish and his native Swedish when growing up,
which helped him during his political and religious career, and exposed him
to a wider circle of influences. His political awakening seems to have
culminated in the early years of the 1760s, when he had secured an
occupation for himself in the clergy. For example, he participated in essay
writing contests that brought him some attention. When he participated in
the Diet (the Swedish Parliament) in 1765-66, he garnered even more
attention as a keen writer and supporter of economic and political freedoms.
This also got him in trouble with some powerful political players
(particularly due to his views on monetary policy) and he was expelled from
the Diet. Chydenius' political career remained tumultuous up until the late
1770s. However, during the later years of his life he remained politically
active and occasionally was a member of the Diet as well.

Why was Chydenius controversial? Some of his writings certainly hit a nerve
as far as the ruling parties were concerned, for example on the issue of
censorship. Chydenius was himself a target for censorship on several
occasions, which made him an even more ardent supporter of free speech. As
he wrote in 1765, "the liberty of a nation is preserved not only by the laws
but by public information and knowledge as to how they are being
administered" (p. 221). He wanted to make sure that no single individual
would be given the singular power to censor political discourse. His fairly
practical solution to this was to expand the number of individuals engaged
in censorship by forming a larger body, scientific or literary, to make the
decisions. This is the issue that also got him in trouble with some of his
peers and political opponents.

While he expressed his views on economic issues in several essays (for
example, in the essay on why Swedes were emigrating from the country, see
the quote in the beginning of the review - he also warned societies of not
focusing too much on armed enemies rather than enemies within, see p. 124),
The National Gain is the most important of his writings in regards to his
economic philosophy. The National Gain was presented to the Estates in 1765,
and it contained many themes similar to Smith's 1776 masterpiece. There
were, however, important differences as well. First, Chydenius' ideas were
less clearly articulated as a cohesive theory; in contrast, he presented an
interesting mix of rather abstract principles and certain clear policy
recommendations. Second, Chydenius was much more influenced by the French
Physiocrats, and his opposition to the staple towns was tied to the idea of
giving rural communities a more equal footing in the economic system.  

"That every individual nation pursues profit as the chief aim of its
economic and political regulations is incontrovertible, but if we consider
the means that each has adopted to achieve that, we observe an incredible
variety" (p. 142). Is this the famous "invisible hand," in its preliminary
form? Not quite, at least explicitly. Chydenius did articulate some ideas
that would feature prominently in the writings of Smith and David Ricardo.
For example, he discussed the idea of an absolute advantage in similar
terms, highlighting that "each individual will of his own accord gravitate
towards the locality and the enterprise where he will most effectively
increase the national profit, provided that the laws do not prevent him from
doing so" (p. 145). He frequently discussed "free enterprise" and
"industriousness" as useful forces in shaping an economy, although he did
not advocate completely free markets rather than "order;" i.e. less
invasive, yet firm governmental oversight of the economy (p. 156). For him,
allowing the freedom of occupation and enterprise would lead to beneficial
outcomes, as for example merchants would know best how to conduct their
business - if they were to try to extract exorbitant rents, their
competitors would drive them out of business (p. 158).

Chydenius argued that freeing up trade and occupations would increase
"national profit" as well, going directly against the existing mercantilist
orthodoxy. Freedom for all occupations would, in his view, guarantee the
largest "national profit," since profit-seeking in all occupations would
lead to the greatest efficiency; even though he did not use the word
"efficiency" directly (p. 162). While Chydenius' thinking emanated from a
fairly practical place, namely the aim to improve the rural economic
communities and existence (similar to Physiocrats, who were against luxury
consumption and profit, the latter being one of the favorite themes of
Chydenius as a beneficial force), he formed an abstract synthesis that was
in many ways similar to Smith. Both were influenced by eighteenth-century
thought and writings, which makes this less surprising. However, it is quite
interesting that Chydenius articulated many themes and concepts similar to
Smith prior to 1776. While that is important, we should not confine
Chydenius to some sort of a footnote of history, a "pre-Adam Smith." His
writings addressed many societal and economic themes, often going beyond the
moral philosophy of Smith. On the other hand, he did not present a coherent
philosophical construct like Smith, which explains why his influence was
much more limited (and language certainly played a role as well).

On the whole, Chydenius was an important eighteenth-century contributor who
offers us a window into Nordic economic and political thought and helps us
understand why and when The Wealth of Nations was created, giving us a more
nuanced view of the time period. I would recommend this volume to all those
interested in eighteenth-century economic thought and theory. This book is
well organized and thought out, and the commentaries by an expert will help
non-Nordic readers by providing more context to the texts. The future
publications of the full volumes will certainly give us an even better view
of Chydenius and the time period. Hopefully many of those texts will be made
available in English as well, so a broader audience will be exposed to these
writings.

Jari Eloranta is an Associate Professor of Comparative Economic and Business
History at Appalachian State University. His publications include several
articles and edited volumes on military and government spending, trade and
conflicts among smaller nations, and Nordic economic and business history.
He is currently working on several projects related to these research areas.
[log in to unmask]

Copyright (c) 2012 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator
([log in to unmask]). Published by EH.Net (November 2012). All EH.Net
reviews are archived at http://www.eh.net/BookReview.

Geographic Location: Europe
Subject: History of Economic Thought; Methodology
Time: 18th Century



ATOM RSS1 RSS2