SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show HTML Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Humberto Barreto <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Mon, 16 May 2022 13:06:45 -0400
Content-Type:
multipart/alternative
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (14 kB) , text/html (15 kB)
Published by EH.Net (May 2022).

Jeff Biddle. *Progress through Regression: The Life Story of the Empirical
Cobb-Douglas Production Function*. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2020. xii + 334 pp. $110 (hardback), ISBN 978-1108492263.

Reviewed for EH.Net by Alexander J. Field, Professor of Economics, Santa
Clara University.



Jeff Biddle has written an intellectual history of the Cobb-Douglas
production function. Actually, he argues, it’s a history not of the
function itself, which predates Cobb and Douglas, but a method for
estimating its parameters using ordinary least squares, to wit, regressing
the log of an output measure on a constant and logs of labor and physical
capital inputs. To be fair, the study offers some of both.

The concept of a production function is best understood in the context of
an agricultural experiment station. The yield of a plant (output) can be
thought of as dependent on the quantities of a variety of inputs: water,
fertilizer, sunlight, for example. The incremental (marginal) products of
these different inputs can be measured through controlled experiment,
varying the amount of one input while everything else is held constant.
From such data one can hope to identify and describe mathematically a
function linking the flow of output to the amounts of various inputs, and
the rapidity with which the incremental product declines with additional
doses, holding other inputs constant. The production function for a
particular plant species would be understood to have a real, objective
basis in biochemistry, and could be assumed to be similar for all specimens
of the same species.

Substitute a particular physical product for an agricultural crop, and the
concept, it would seem, can be extended to manufacturing. The production
function would now reflect an underlying engineering reality and could be
assumed similar in different establishments or firms producing the same
good. Given observational data on different combinations of inputs, the
underlying function could in principle be identified.

But that’s not what mathematician Charles Cobb and economist Paul Douglas
actually attempted. Initially they ran time series regressions where the
unit of observation was the entire U.S. manufacturing sector, followed by a
study on Massachusetts and then estimates using data from the state of
Victoria in Australia. There were and are multiple problems in extending
the biological analogy to these larger aggregates and including on the
right-hand side just two aggregated inputs, labor and capital. Both are
heterogeneous, capital much more so than labor. One can perhaps argue that
labor has a natural metric, the person-hour or person-year, but there is no
such metric for the wide variety of physical capital goods. Although one
would like measures of capital service flow, one will almost invariably be
stuck with gross or net stock data serving as proxies. And even if
depreciation in market value of different vintages of different types can
be measured accurately, service flow deterioration will in almost all cases
run more slowly than the decline in market value (depreciation). The
extreme case is Oliver Wendell Holmes’ one hoss shay, which fell apart all
at once after 100 years. The service flow (and presumably the rental rate)
remained the same for a century, but a 98-year-old shay would still command
a much lower market value than one which was new or almost new.

Robert Solow dismissed the prospect of calculating capital service flows as
“utopian” (1957, p. 314), but today the Bureau of Labor Statistics and
other OECD statistical agencies do make a run at it, distinguishing between
productive stocks, constructed to grow *pari passu* with service flows, and
wealth stocks (what the Bureau of Economic Analysis calculates). Economics
researchers seem largely unaware of these procedures, or, arguing that
deterioration in service flow runs geometrically at the same rate as the
declines in market value, maintain that a distinction between productive
and wealth stocks is unnecessary.

Assuming one does have measures of productive stocks, should there be a
utilization adjustment? Douglas felt as did Solow and others after him,
that one was needed. My own view is that its desirability is questionable,
given that deterioration of fixed capital service flow is largely
unaffected by how intensively buildings or equipment are used. The rate at
which a building’s roof wears out, or a machine becomes obsolete, are
illustrative of forces other than utilization that can govern both
deterioration and depreciation. Douglas regretted he was not able to make
such an adjustment; Solow made one.

There remains the problem of how one aggregates a sectoral output
consisting of many different types of physical products. Is it acceptable
to use value added? And the challenges continue. Assuming one can develop
plausible measures of the service flows from aggregated labor and capital,
is it reasonable to assume that the production functions used in making
different products are all the same? Really? Elasticities of substitution
are the same, as are the marginal products of ‘capital’ and ‘labor’?
Doesn’t that present serious aggregation problems? And, in a cross-section
regression, if the production functions are indeed the same across
different products, and both market and input markets are all perfectly
competitive, wouldn’t all firms and all sectors exhibit the same
proportions of capital to labor (at least in long term equilibrium), in
which case the regression would suffer from extreme multicollinearity,
making it nearly impossible to estimate parameters of an aggregate
production function with any degree of precision?

The challenges seem daunting. And yet I would hazard that a sizable
majority of economists and economic historians (present company included)
refer in their research and teaching to Cobb-Douglas functions, often
acutely aware that they are engaged in some hand waving. In describing the
initial and continuing reaction to the Cobb-Douglas enterprise, Biddle’s
book discusses almost all of these concerns, and gives economic researchers
an opportunity to reflect on the nature of their own handwaving and whether
or not it is justified given the uses to which their inquiries are put. It
is particularly useful to revisit the language used by scholars such as
Solow (pp. 248-49) or Zvi Griliches (pp. 294-95) as they finesse these
issues and compare their rationales with one’s own.

The book is primarily focused on developments from the 1920s through the
1970s and is divided into two main parts, each with three chapters,
followed by a concluding chapter (part III). The materials studied for the
most part are published journal articles, and the method for each is to
provide an explication of the key arguments along with varying degrees of
commentary and evaluation. Following a brief introduction, chapter 1 covers
the initial time series studies as described in Cobb and Douglas’s
1928 *American
Economic Review* article and Douglas’s 1934 book, *The Theory of Wages*,
along with initial reactions and criticisms, and subsequent time series
studies by Douglas and coauthors.

Chapter 2 is principally focused on debates with economist Horst
Mendershausen, who came at Cobb and Douglas from several directions. The
most damaging argument was that one could not simply assume “the”
production function remained unchanged over multiple decades, and use
variation in capital and labor inputs to identify a function that was in
fact a moving target. Mendershausen would not be the last to raise this
objection. It is perhaps not accidental that around this time Douglas
switched from time series to cross-section studies. This avoided some of
the hoary problems of adjusting for price changes of capital goods in
accounting for depreciation and net additions in building up an inflation
adjusted time series of a physical capital wealth stock. But, in moving to
cross sectional data with different industries serving as the unit of
analysis, one could still wonder whether all industries faced a similar
production function. Cleverly, Douglas used the possibility that a few did
not in explaining large residuals (differences between the predicted and
actual value of production based on his regression estimates) (p. 100).
Other complaints voiced by Mendershausen revolved around the fact that all
three of the key series moved upward fairly systematically over time – as
well as questions about whether it was reasonable to maintain the
hypothesis that output was the dependent variable and labor and capital
were independent right-hand variables. A number of authors argued that the
question of which was dependent and which independent should be decided by
“objective” statistical inquiry, whereas Douglas argued, I think
convincingly, that one could use knowledge about how the world works to
justify the assumption that labor and capital service flows produced
output, rather than vice versa.

Douglas’s academic career was interrupted in 1942 when he enlisted in the
Marines and then, following a short postwar coda, ended when in 1948 he ran
successfully for the U.S. Senate. Chapter 3, the final chapter in part I,
covers Douglas’s presidential address to the American Economic Association
(AEA), in which he summed up his contributions, as well as additional
commentary and criticism from the 1940s. The latter included Jan
Tinbergen’s observation that in the cross-sectional studies, variations
across industries in capital-labor ratios could come about only if
different industries had different production functions, or if different
regions faced different labor or capital supply conditions, and thus
different factor prices. But the latter could not be the case if input
markets were truly competitive. The chapter continued with discussion of
papers by Melvin Reder, Martin Bronfenbrenner (an earlier coauthor with
Douglas) and Jacob Marschak and William J. Andrews. In his valedictory
address to the AEA, Douglas mentioned none of these (p. 130).

Part II of the book is concerned with “diffusion” of Douglas’s research
program, spotlighting research in two areas that grew out of his
initiative: agricultural economics (chapter 5) and growth accounting
(chapter 6). Prior to developing these two “case studies”, in chapter 4
Biddle covers three somewhat unrelated developments during the 1950s: the
treatment of the Cobb-Douglas research program in the first econometrics
textbooks, the 1957 critique by E.H. Phelps-Brown, and the development of
the CES (constant elasticity of substitution) production function of which
the Cobb-Douglas function was a special case. Chapter 5 is organized around
the work of Earl Heady and a group at Iowa State University. The appeal of
the research program within that subdiscipline has already been mentioned.
Even where the studies were observational rather than experimental, the
greater prevalence of single product firms and the practical questions
farmers were concerned with helps explain why the research program was
attractive.

Chapter 6 covers growth accounting. With the burgeoning postwar interest in
economic growth came empirical attempts to partition advance into the
portion attributable on the one hand to input growth conventionally
measured and on the other hand to scientific, technological, and
organizational progress. The fundamental growth accounting equation is
obtained by differentiating both sides of the Cobb-Douglas function with
respect to time and can be estimated by running the change in the log of
output against a constant and changes in the logs of capital and labor
inputs. In that sense the efforts are an offshoot of the Cobb-Douglas
program. Biddle acknowledges however, that few growth accounting studies
used this method, instead preferring a pure accounting exercise, with the
residual calculated as the difference between real output growth and a
weighted average of the two key inputs.

One can still argue that growth accounting has a lineage stretching back to
Cobb-Douglas. These weights are usually based on factor shares, and Cobb
and Douglas maintained that the coefficients on labor and capital they were
estimating should equal marginal productivities, which in turn would be
reflected in factor shares. But one can question whether that linkage
really matters for growth accounting. One of the attractions of such work
is that it can be less demanding of commitment to some of the standard
production function baggage (p. 280). Even if one remains agnostic about
marginal productivity theory, one can argue that weighting by factor shares
remains as good a practice as any, and proceed accordingly. Biddle makes an
interesting point in crediting Solow with explicitly tying the growth
accounting program to the production function framework, insisting that one
was separating shifts of a production function from movements along it (p.
251). Indeed, Biddle sees that as Solow’s most important contribution,
since little else in the 1957 article can be said to be truly original.

This book can be read profitably by those with interests in the twentieth
century history of economics and econometrics, and, more specifically, in
production functions and attempts to estimate them. I acknowledge and
respect the efforts of the author to be fair to all participants, but at
times I wished for a more consistent balance of exposition and evaluation.
A work such as this can add value if the author can capture with more
clarity and in shorter compass what the original author(s) argued. Simply
recapitulating the main arguments, however, can invite readers to ask
whether it would not be better simply to read the original texts, a query I
frequently posed and acted upon (almost all of the articles are available
on JSTOR). Now and again in the book Biddle offers his own judgments. I
would have appreciated more articulation of his point of view.

A minor issue: the author repeatedly uses the words homogenous and
homogeneous interchangeably. Only the latter is appropriate in charactering
a mathematical function.

Reference:

Solow, Robert M. 1957. “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production
Function.” *Review of Economics and Statistics* 39 (August): 312–20.



Alexander J. Field is the Michel and Mary Orradre Professor of Economics at
Santa Clara University. He is the author of *A Great Leap Forward: 1930s
Depression and U.S. Economic Growth* (Yale University Press, 2011) and *The
Economic Consequences of U.S. Mobilization for the Second World War* (Yale
University Press, October 2022).

Copyright (c) 2022 by EH.Net. All rights reserved. This work may be copied
for non-profit educational uses if proper credit is given to the author and
the list. For other permission, please contact the EH.Net Administrator (
[log in to unmask]). Published by EH.Net (May 2022). All EH.Net reviews
are archived at https://www.eh.net/book-reviews.


ATOM RSS1 RSS2