SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show HTML Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Humberto Barreto <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Mon, 8 Aug 2022 08:38:16 -0400
Content-Type:
multipart/alternative
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (23 kB) , text/html (38 kB)
[Selections by Humberto Barreto for SHOE list.]


nep-hpe <http://nep.repec.org/nep-hpe.html> New Economics Papers
<http://nep.repec.org/> on History and Philosophy of Economics

Issue of 2022‒08‒08
papers chosen by
Erik Thomson <http://econpapers.repec.org/RAS/pth72.htm>
University of Manitoba <http://umanitoba.ca/>
------------------------------

   1. Is God giving or trading? Super Isaiam, 55, 1: Thomas Aquinas's first
   use of 'just price'
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p1> By Pierre
   Januard
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Pierre%20Januard>
   2. Institutional Economics and Dewey's Instrumentalism
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p2> By Malcolm
   Rutherford
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Malcolm%20Rutherford>
   3. Setting the Record Straight on the Libertarian South African
   Economist W. H. Hutt and James M. Buchanan
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p3> By William
   Darity Jr.
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=William%20Darity%20Jr.>
   ; M'Balou Camara
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=M%27Balou%20Camara>;
Nancy
   MacLean
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Nancy%20MacLean>
   4. At the Boundaries of the Trading Sphere: The Appearance of the 'Just
   Price' in Thomas Aquinas's Commentary on the Sentences
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p4> By Pierre
   Januard
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Pierre%20Januard>
   5. An Economic Defense of Multiple Antitrust Goals: Reversing Income
   Inequality and Promoting Political Democracy
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p5> By Mark
   Glick <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Mark%20Glick>
   6. History of science and its utopian reconstructions
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p6> By Paskins,
   Matthew
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Paskins,%20Matthew>
   7. Saving the lost ones
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p7> By
Glendinning,
   Simon
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Glendinning,%20Simon>
   8. Shaky foundations Central bank independence in the 21st century
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p8> By Laurence
   Scialom
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Laurence%20Scialom>;
Gaëtan
   Le Quang
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Ga%C3%ABtan%20Le%20Quang>
   ; Jérôme Deyris
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=J%C3%A9r%C3%B4me%20Deyris>
   9. The View of Knowledge: An Institutional Theory of Differences in
   Educational Quality
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p9> By Henrekson,
   Magnus
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Henrekson,%20Magnus>;
Wennström,
   Johan
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Wennstr%C3%B6m,%20Johan>
   10. The Philosophical Justifications of the “Fair Innings Argument” and
   Related Controversies
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-4677687815792050609_p10> By Clémence
   Thebaut
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Cl%C3%A9mence%20Thebaut>
   ; Paul-Loup Weil-Dubuc
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Paul-Loup%20Weil-Dubuc>
   ; Jérôme Wittwer
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=J%C3%A9r%C3%B4me%20Wittwer>

------------------------------

   1. Is God giving or trading? Super Isaiam, 55, 1: Thomas Aquinas's first
   use of 'just price'
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03658155>
   By: Pierre Januard
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Pierre%20Januard> (PHARE
   - Philosophie, Histoire et Analyse des Représentations Économiques - UP1 -
   Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne)
   Abstract: The phrase 'just price' first appears in Aquinas's Commentary
   on the Book of Isaiah (1252). Interestingly, even in this early work
   Aquinas introduces the notion of price to comment on a verse, a term which
   had in fact disappeared with the Vulgate Latin translation, on which
   Aquinas nevertheless relied, as it had also from the Fathers's
   commentaries. Aquinas here provides the founding elements of his later
   analyses: the role of the price in ensuring the justice of exchange, but
   also the diversity of possible exchange ratios, not necessarily referring
   to price, in order to account for limit cases within an exchange framework.
   Keywords: Thomas Aquinas,Scholastics,just price,risk JEL classification:
   B11
   Date: 2022–05–03
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03658155&r=
   2. Institutional Economics and Dewey's Instrumentalism
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:vic:vicddp:2008>
   By: Malcolm Rutherford
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Malcolm%20Rutherford>
(Department
   of Economics, University of Victoria)
   Abstract: Previous discussions concerning the relationship between John
   Dewey’s pragmatic instrumentalism and institutional economics have focused
   on Clarence Ayres and on issues of valuation. This paper gives attention to
   the actual conduct of economic investigations by institutionalists such as
   Wesley Mitchell, Walton Hamilton, and John R. Commons. It is argued that
   many aspects of Dewey’s instrumentalism are clearly displayed in the
   problem centered, investigational, and experimental methods employed by
   institutionalists, and in their commitment to problem solving and social
   control. The association of institutionalist methods with Dewey’s
   instrumentalism implies that many of the standard criticisms of
   institutionalist methods are misplaced. These criticisms, that
   institutionalism lacked proper theoretical perspective and produced work
   that was overly descriptive, have been made predominantly from a logical
   positivist methodological perspective, and ignore Dewey’s notions of
   science that informed the institutionalist approach. Appraising
   institutionalist successes and failures from the point of view of the
   methodology they actually adopted provides a much more nuanced criticism,
   one based on the strengths and weaknesses of the underlying instrumentalist
   methods they employed. In particular, some serious difficulties with the
   application of Dewey’s experimentalism to social science are located.
   Keywords: Institutionalism, Instrumentalism, John Dewey, Wesley
   Mitchell, Walton Hamilton, J. R. Commons
   Date: 2022–07–12
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:vic:vicddp:2008&r=
   3. Setting the Record Straight on the Libertarian South African
   Economist W. H. Hutt and James M. Buchanan
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:thk:wpaper:inetwp184>
   By: William Darity Jr.
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=William%20Darity%20Jr.>
(Duke
   University); M'Balou Camara
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=M%27Balou%20Camara> (Duke
   University); Nancy MacLean
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Nancy%20MacLean> (Duke
   University)
   Abstract: In their stormy response to Nancy MacLean's book Democracy in
   Chains, some academics on the libertarian right have conducted a concerted
   defense of Nobel Laureate James Buchanan's credentials as an anti-racist,
   or at least a non-racist. An odd component of their argument is a claim of
   innocence by association: the peripatetic South African economist and Mont
   Pelerin Society founding member William Harold Hutt was against apartheid;
   Buchanan was a friend and supporter of Hutt; therefore, Buchanan could not
   have been abetting segregationists with his support for public funding of
   segregationist private schools. At the core of this chain of argument is
   the inference that Hutt's opposition to apartheid proves that Hutt himself
   was committed to racial equality. However, just as there were white
   supremacists who opposed slavery in the United States, we demonstrate Hutt
   was a white supremacist who opposed apartheid in South Africa. We document
   how Hutt embraced notions of black inferiority, even in The Economics of
   the Colour Bar, his most ferocious attack on apartheid. Whether or not
   innocence by association is a sound defense of anyone's ideology or
   conduct, Hutt, himself, was not innocent of white supremacy.
   Keywords: Race and economics; James Buchanan, Libertarianism, South
   Africa, Public Choice.
   JEL: B25 I24 I28 J15 N17 N12 N37
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=B25%20I24%20I28%20J15%20N17%20N12%20N37>
   Date: 2022–05–26
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:thk:wpaper:inetwp184&r=
   4. At the Boundaries of the Trading Sphere: The Appearance of the 'Just
   Price' in Thomas Aquinas's Commentary on the Sentences
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03658417>
   By: Pierre Januard
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Pierre%20Januard> (PHARE
   - Philosophie, Histoire et Analyse des Représentations Économiques - UP1 -
   Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne)
   Abstract: The term 'just price' appears only twice in the Commentary on
   the Sentences, the most important of Thomas Aquinas's early works. Yet
   these little known and seemingly incidental appearances, related to a
   non-tradable good and a semi-tradable good, are in fact fundamental and
   decisive: they offer a new way of understanding the Thomasian just price as
   an analogy of justice; they highlight the role of price in reducing the
   risk of lack of information about the justice of exchange; they allow the
   market to be delimited; and they indicate how, through paying particular
   attention to the goods, Aquinas implements an objective approach that
   reduces the subjective risk concerning the agents and their hidden
   intentions.
   Keywords: Thomas Aquinas,Scholastics,just price,risk
   Date: 2022–05–03
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03658417&r=
   5. An Economic Defense of Multiple Antitrust Goals: Reversing Income
   Inequality and Promoting Political Democracy
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:thk:wpaper:inetwp181>
   By: Mark Glick
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Mark%20Glick> (University
   of Utah)
   Abstract: Two recent papers by prominent antitrust scholars argue that a
   revived antitrust movement can help reverse the dramatic rise in economic
   inequality and the erosion of political democracy in the United States.
   Both papers rely on the legislative history of the key antitrust statutes
   to support their case. Not surprisingly, their recommendations have been
   met with alarm in some quarters and with skepticism in others. Such
   proposals by antitrust reformers are often contrasted with the Consumer
   Welfare Standard that pervades antitrust policy today. The Consumer Welfare
   Standard suffers from several defects: (1) It employs a narrow, unworkable
   measure of welfare; (2) It excludes important sources of welfare based on
   the assumption that antitrust seeks only to maximize wealth; (3) It assumes
   a constant and equal individual marginal utility of money; and (4) It is
   often combined with extraneous ideological goals. Even with these defects,
   however, if applied consistent with its theoretical underpinnings, the
   consideration of the transfer of labor rents resulting from a merger or
   dominant firm conduct is supported by the Consumer Welfare Standard.
   Moreover, even when only consumers (and not producers) are deemed relevant,
   the welfare of labor still should consistently be considered part of
   consumer welfare. In contrast, fostering political democracy—a prominent
   traditional antitrust goal that was jettisoned by the Chicago School—falls
   outside the Consumer Welfare Standard in any of its constructs. To
   undergird such important broader goals requires that the Consumer Welfare
   Standard be replaced with the General Welfare Standard. The General Welfare
   Standard consists of modern welfare economics modified to accommodate
   objective analyses of human welfare and purged of inconsistencies.
   Keywords: New Brandeis School, Antitrust economics, Antitrust law,
   Neoliberal Economic Theory, Chicago School Economics, History of Antitrust
   law; market concentration; corporation size.
   JEL: K21 L40 N12
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=K21%20L40%20N12>
   Date: 2022–03–21
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:thk:wpaper:inetwp181&r=
   6. History of science and its utopian reconstructions
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:ehl:lserod:109300>
   By: Paskins, Matthew
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Paskins,%20Matthew>
   Abstract: In recent years explicitly utopian visions have reappeared
   across the political spectrum. To a surprising degree these visions have
   drawn on histories and science and technology. What should scholars of
   Science and Technology Studies (STS) and History and Philosophy of Science
   (HPS) make of these developments? The concept of utopia has often been
   treated with considerable distrust in these fields, as an indication of
   closed end-directed blueprints, or as an indication of fantasies of
   limitless technological improvement and purification of categories.
   Alongside this uneasiness, however, HPS and STS scholars have also
   projected transformative ambitions, seeking to recover from the past
   different ways of knowing and relating to the human and non-human world. By
   engaging with critiques of utopia from thinkers including Karl Popper, Otto
   Neurath, Bruno Latour, Isabelle Stengers and Donna Haraway, and exploring
   some of the utopian strands which have recurred in studies of science and
   technology—including the longing for integration, the association of
   science with planning, and the ways in which feminist scholars have
   envisaged alternative forms of science—we can understand the ongoing, and
   often unrecognised, utopian dimensions of HPS and STS.
   Keywords: Anthropocene; Feminist theory; Integration; Planning;
   Pluralism; Utopia; European Union's Horizon 2020 research and innovation
   programme (grant agreement number 694732- NARRATIVENSCIENCE)
   JEL: B10 B20
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=B10%20B20>
   Date: 2020–06–20
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ehl:lserod:109300&r=
   7. Saving the lost ones
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:ehl:lserod:115457>
   By: Glendinning, Simon
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Glendinning,%20Simon>
   Abstract: In an essay on the modern idea of political equality, Bernard
   Williams contrasts what he calls ‘the human point of view’ with a point of
   view marked by what he calls a ‘technical or professional attitude’. While
   the latter is concerned with conspicuous structures of someone’s life that
   might be by occupied by another, the former concerns an attitude towards a
   singular person, what Wittgenstein calls ‘an attitude towards a soul’ – an
   attitude characteristically exemplified in the relation to the other who is
   a friend. It is the one who is in view under such a singularising gaze that
   seems to be lost as soon as we start counting others, counting our friends.
   The paper explores the general haunting of the modern-Western idea of all
   people’s equality by the hazy spectre of what is disclosed by this
   singularising gaze, and asks how we might organise a response politically
   to the in each case unique and singular relation to the unique and singular
   other we call the friend – the one who is both altogether other and my
   equal.
   JEL: B14 B24 P2 P3
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=B14%20B24%20P2%20P3>
   Date: 2022–06–01
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ehl:lserod:115457&r=
   8. Shaky foundations Central bank independence in the 21st century
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:drm:wpaper:2022-16>
   By: Laurence Scialom
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Laurence%20Scialom>;
Gaëtan
   Le Quang
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Ga%C3%ABtan%20Le%20Quang>
   ; Jérôme Deyris
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=J%C3%A9r%C3%B4me%20Deyris>
   Abstract: Central bank independence (CBI) has often been presented as a
   superior institutional arrangement demonstrated by economists in the 1980s
   for achieving a common good in a non-partisan manner. In this article, we
   argue that this view must be challenged. First, research in the history of
   economic facts and thought shows that the idea of CBI is not new, and was
   adopted under peculiar socio-historical conditions, in response to
   particular interests. Rather than an indisputable progress in economic
   science, CBI is the foundation for a particular configuration of the
   monetary regime, perishable like its predecessors. Secondly, we argue that
   the simplistic case imagined by the CBI theory (the setting of a single
   interest rate disconnected from political pressures) is long overdue. For
   nearly two decades, central banks have been increasing their footprint on
   the economy, embarking on large asset purchase programs and adopting
   macroprudential policies. This pro-activism forces independent central
   banks to constantly address new distributional - and therefore political -
   issues, leading to a growing number of criticisms of their actions with
   regard to inequality or climate change. This growing gap between theory and
   practices makes plausible a further shift of the institutional arrangement
   towards a democratization of monetary policy.
   Keywords: central bank independence, monetary policy, macroprudential
   policy
   JEL: E58 G28 N20
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=E58%20G28%20N20>
   Date: 2022
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:drm:wpaper:2022-16&r=
   9. The View of Knowledge: An Institutional Theory of Differences in
   Educational Quality <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:hhs:iuiwop:1432>
   By: Henrekson, Magnus
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Henrekson,%20Magnus>
(Research
   Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN)); Wennström, Johan
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Wennstr%C3%B6m,%20Johan>
(Research
   Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN))
   Abstract: This essay argues that the most crucial institution of any
   school system is its view of knowledge—from which virtually all other
   aspects of a school are derived: the content of its curricula, its
   pedagogical practices, and the incentives that motivate its members. To
   make this case, we outline the two main conflicting views of knowledge, the
   classical view and the postmodern social constructivist view. According to
   the classical view, the purpose of schooling is to give students objective
   knowledge and skills that they cannot acquire in any way other than through
   hierarchical instruction in well-defined disciplines. The social
   constructivist view rejects the existence of objective knowledge. This
   rejection translates to a preference for student-directed pedagogy, the
   mixing of instructional fields, and an emphasis on developing general
   critical thinking skills rather than on acquiring domain-specific
   knowledge. Using the history of education in Sweden as an example, our
   analysis suggests that the recent decline in educational quality in the
   Western democracies can be remedied by a paradigm shift in the governing
   view of knowledge toward the classical view.
   Keywords: Communal knowledge; Institutions; Postmodernism; Social
   constructivism; Thought style; Views of knowledge
   JEL: H42 H44 H75 I22 I28 L88
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=H42%20H44%20H75%20I22%20I28%20L88>
   Date: 2022–06–22
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hhs:iuiwop:1432&r=
   10. The Philosophical Justifications of the “Fair Innings Argument” and
   Related Controversies
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03670001>
   By: Clémence Thebaut
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Cl%C3%A9mence%20Thebaut>
(NET
   - Neuroépidémiologie Tropicale - INSERM - Institut National de la Santé et
   de la Recherche Médicale - Institut d'Epidémiologie Neurologique et de
   Neurologie Tropicale - CHU Limoges - GEIST - Institut Génomique,
   Environnement, Immunité, Santé, Thérapeutique - UNILIM - Université de
   Limoges, LEDa - Laboratoire d'Economie de Dauphine - CNRS - Centre National
   de la Recherche Scientifique - IRD - Institut de Recherche pour le
   Développement - Université Paris Dauphine-PSL - PSL - Université Paris
   sciences et lettres, PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres, UNILIM -
   Université de Limoges); Paul-Loup Weil-Dubuc
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Paul-Loup%20Weil-Dubuc>
(Université
   Paris-Saclay); Jérôme Wittwer
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=J%C3%A9r%C3%B4me%20Wittwer>
(BPH
   - Bordeaux population health - UB - Université de Bordeaux - Institut de
   Santé Publique, d'Épidémiologie et de Développement (ISPED) - INSERM -
   Institut National de la Santé et de la Recherche Médicale)
   Abstract: Financing innovative and costly treatments in various
   therapeutic fields entails a number of problems in countries where costs
   are covered by public services. Providing these drugs is forcing actors to
   define the maximum sums of money society is willing to spend for given
   health improvements. This raises the question of whether maximum financing
   should vary according individuals' circumstances, such as the rareness of a
   disease, lifestyles, social inequalities experienced over a life time, etc.
   This article examines a particular priority, namely that given to the
   youngest patients, such prioritising usually refers to the "fair innings
   argument" (FIA). The challenge is to identify if, and on the basis of what
   arguments, collective choices should take into account age in the name of a
   right to live the time required for a complete life, within a context of
   the scarcity of resources and the pluralism of values. Three arguments are
   considered. At first we consider that FIA could be justified by the
   objective of equalizing the opportunities of well-being. Next, we proposed
   justifying the fair innings argument with the aim of equalizing the time
   provided to individuals to achieve their plan of life, in accordance with
   Rawls's theory of justice as fairness. Finally, we proposed considering the
   FIA as being justified because of the goal of equalizing the time provided
   to individuals to accept death. These three arguments, of course, have many
   limitations, some of which we have highlighted.
   Date: 2022–05–17
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03670001&r=

------------------------------
This nep-hpe issue is ©2022 by  <http://econpapers.repec.org/RAS/pth72.htm>Erik
Thomson. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It
may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If
distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org.
For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese
<http://novarese.org/> at <[log in to unmask]>. Put “NEP” in the
subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by
the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.


ATOM RSS1 RSS2