SHOE Archives

Societies for the History of Economics

SHOE@YORKU.CA

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show HTML Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Humberto Barreto <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Societies for the History of Economics <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Tue, 23 Aug 2022 20:40:54 -0400
Content-Type:
multipart/alternative
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (16 kB) , text/html (25 kB)
[Selections by Humberto Barreto for SHOE list.]

nep-hpe <http://nep.repec.org/nep-hpe.html> New Economics Papers
<http://nep.repec.org/> on History and Philosophy of Economics

Issue of 2022‒08‒22
papers chosen by
Erik Thomson <http://econpapers.repec.org/RAS/pth72.htm>
University of Manitoba <http://umanitoba.ca/>
------------------------------

   1. Karl Marx´s Theory of Capitalism Exposition, Critique, and Appraisal
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-7723881999352099564_p1> By Escudé,
   Guillermo J.
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Escud%C3%A9,%20Guillermo%20J.>
   2. Sen and Sraffa: Description as Theory
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-7723881999352099564_p2> By Syed
   Mohib Ali
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Syed%20Mohib%20Ali>
   3. ECONOMIC MODELS, REALISM AND SIMILARITY
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-7723881999352099564_p3> By Leonardo
   Ivarola
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Leonardo%20Ivarola>
   4. Homo economicus to model human behavior is ethically doubtful and
   mathematically inconsistent
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-7723881999352099564_p4> By M.
   Lunkenheimer
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=M.%20Lunkenheimer>; A.
   Kracklauer
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=A.%20Kracklauer>; G.
   Klinkova
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=G.%20Klinkova>; M.
   Grabinski
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=M.%20Grabinski>
   5. Kantian Epistemology in Examination of the Axiomatic Principles of
   Economics: the Synthetic a Priori in the Economic Structure of Society
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-7723881999352099564_p5> By Mughal,
   Adil Ahmad
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Mughal,%20Adil%20Ahmad>
   6. From Addition to Multiplication: The Labour Theory Of Value and the
   Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Part One: Profit and Surplus-Value in
   light of Transaction Costs
   <https://mail.google.com/mail/u/0/#m_-7723881999352099564_p6> By Alberto
   Battistini
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Alberto%20Battistini>

------------------------------

   1. Karl Marx´s Theory of Capitalism Exposition, Critique, and Appraisal
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:pra:mprapa:113685>
   By: Escudé, Guillermo J.
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Escud%C3%A9,%20Guillermo%20J.>
   Abstract: This book gives a clear synthesis of Marx’s theory of
   Capitalism and its relation with economic theory as it evolved over the
   course of the last 300 years. It places Marx’s though in perspective,
   comparing it with the main aspects of the economic theories that preceded
   it, including not only the Classical Adam Smith and David Ricardo but also
   economists like Cantillon, Turgot, and Ramsay that Marx chose to ignore
   with respect to the crucial issue of entrepreneurship because it was
   incompatible with his Theory of Surplus Value. But the book also contrasts
   Marx’s theory with Walras’, the Neoclassical economist whose influence on
   contemporary mainstream economic theory was most lasting. The analytical
   aspects of Marx’s theory are rigorously expressed by means of the technique
   of Input-Output Analysis, which is explained from the most elementary level
   in order to make the book self-contained. Each of the multiple topics of
   Marx’s complex and refined theory is explained in detail, including his
   theory of money, the heterogeneity in kinds of labor and in productive
   techniques, the turnover of capital, Simple and Extended Reproduction, his
   theory of the economic cycle, his theory of ground rent, his theory of
   productive and unproductive labor, and his view of the main tendencies of
   capitalist society. The book is structured in accordance with the
   development process of Marx’s thought. Hence, it begins with the life
   project he generated in his youth and drove him from the study of history
   and philosophy to that of Political Economy, on the one hand, and political
   praxis, on the other. Hence, Parts I, II, and IV of the book respectively
   address A) the philosophical-methodological foundations of his scientific
   endeavor (his Historical Materialism); B) his scientific theory of
   capitalist society as expressed in Capital; and C) his political thought
   and praxis, which had enormous effects over the course of the 20th century.
   Part III of the book addresses our critique of Marx’s theory of Capitalism.
   Beyond our criticisms, however, the book shows that Marx made important
   contributions to the comprehension of the functioning of Capitalism in the
   more conventional part of his theory, which we denominate ‘exoteric’ in
   order to contrast it with his ‘esoteric’ Theory of Surplus Value which was
   the foundation of his view of the exploitation of wage labor in Capitalism.
   Keywords: Marx's theory of capitalism; Marx's theory of surplus value
   and its critique; Comparison of Marx's and Walras' economic theories;
   Historical Materialism; Marx's political project and its critique;
   appraisal of Marx's influence in the light of the world events of the 20th
   century.
   JEL: B00 B31 B40 B51
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=B00%20B31%20B40%20B51>
   Date: 2021
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:113685&r=
   2. Sen and Sraffa: Description as Theory
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:usi:wpaper:882>
   By: Syed Mohib Ali
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Syed%20Mohib%20Ali>
   Abstract: The article engages with Amartya Sen’s interpretation of Piero
   Sraffa’s Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (PCMC). Sen has
   the distinction of highlighting the philosophical and methodological
   aspects of Sraffa’s work. In this regard, Sen has highlighted the role of
   counterfactuals in economic theory and the role of value theory in
   political economy as a matter of ‘social communication’. On these two
   issues, there is considerable discussion in recent Sraffian scholarship
   that is concerned with the significance of Sraffa’s critique of marginalist
   theory and the rehabilitation of classical economics. The article
   scrutinizes Sen’s interpretation of PCMC and highlights several noteworthy
   contributions and insights. While being sympathetic to the substantive
   points of criticism entailed by PCMC, Sen misunderstands Sraffa’s ‘critique
   of economic theory’ and the reasoning involved in such a critique. A
   critical reading reveals that Sen’s interpretation of Sraffa is more
   reflective of his own work on the ‘choice basis of description’ than an
   appreciation of Sraffa’s theoretical project. Despite the
   misunderstandings, the article highlights the similarities in vision
   between Sen’s interpretation of Sraffa and Sraffa’s revival of classical
   economics. By undertaking such a critical reading, the article raises
   important issues about method and the scope of economic enquiries
   Date: 2022–06
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:usi:wpaper:882&r=
   3. ECONOMIC MODELS, REALISM AND SIMILARITY
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:ake:iiepdt:202163>
   By: Leonardo Ivarola
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Leonardo%20Ivarola>
(Instituto
   Interdisciplinario de Economía Política de Buenos Aires - UBA - CONICET)
   Abstract: In the present paper it is argued that differences among
   economic models are basically differences in their selected part of the
   real world these models try to account for. Therefore, their range of
   applicability to a target system turns out to be important for their
   selection to particular purposes. In this respect, an approach based on the
   similarity of models to a target system and to the modelers’ purposes is
   provided. It is also argued that models vary in values of similarity. These
   values will help agents to select the model that best meets the role of
   examining some phenomenon of interest.
   Keywords: Similarity, Economic models, Mechanisms, Possibility tree,
   Substantive assumptions, Domain of applicability
   JEL: B41 <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=B41>
   Date: 2021–06
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ake:iiepdt:202163&r=
   4. Homo economicus to model human behavior is ethically doubtful and
   mathematically inconsistent
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:arx:papers:2207.02902>
   By: M. Lunkenheimer
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=M.%20Lunkenheimer>; A.
   Kracklauer
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=A.%20Kracklauer>; G.
   Klinkova
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=G.%20Klinkova>; M.
   Grabinski
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=M.%20Grabinski>
   Abstract: In many models in economics or business a dominantly
   self-interested homo economicus is assumed. Unfortunately (or fortunately),
   humans are in general not homines economici as e.g. the ultimatum game
   shows. This leads to the fact that all these models are at least doubtful.
   Moreover, economists started to set a quantitative value for the feeling of
   social justice, altruism, or envy and the like to execute utilitarian
   calculation. Besides being ethically doubtful, it delivers an explanation
   in hindsight with little predicting power. We use examples from game theory
   to show its arbitrariness. It is even possible that a stable Nash
   equilibrium can be calculated while it does not exist at all, due to the
   wide differences in human values. Finally, we show that assigned numbers
   for envy or altruism and the like do not build a field (in a mathematical
   sense). As there is no homomorphism to real numbers or a subset of it, any
   calculation is generally invalid or arbitrary. There is no (easy) way to
   fix the problem. One has to go back to ethical concepts like the
   categorical imperative or use at most semi quantitative approaches like
   considering knaves and knights. Mathematically one can only speculate
   whether e.g. surreal numbers can make ethics calculable.
   Date: 2022–07
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.02902&r=
   5. Kantian Epistemology in Examination of the Axiomatic Principles of
   Economics: the Synthetic a Priori in the Economic Structure of Society
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:pra:mprapa:113677>
   By: Mughal, Adil Ahmad
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Mughal,%20Adil%20Ahmad>
   Abstract: Transcendental Analytic, in Critique of Pure Reason, combines
   the space and time as conditions of the possibility of phenomenon from
   Transcendental Aesthetic with the pure magnitude-intuition notion. The
   property of continuity as a qualitative result of the additive magnitude
   brings the possibility of connecting with experience, even though only as a
   potential because of the a priori necessity from assumption, as
   syntheticity of the a priori task of a scientific method of philosophy
   given by Kant, which precludes the application of categories to something
   not empirically reducible to the content of such a category's corresponding
   and possible object. This continuity as the qualitative result of a priori
   constructed notion of magnitude lies as a fundamental assumption and
   property of, what in Microeconomic theory is called as, 'choice rules'
   which combine the potentially-empirical and practical budget-price pairs
   with preference relations. This latter result is the purest qualitative
   side of the choice rules' otherwise autonomously quantitative nature. The
   theoretical, barring the empirical, nature of this qualitative result is a
   synthetic a priori truth, which, if at all, it should be, if the axiomatic
   structure of economic theory is held to be correct. It has a potentially
   verifiable content as its possible object in the form of quantitative
   price-budget pairs, yet, the object that serves the respective Kantian
   category is qualitative itself which is utility. This article explores the
   validity of Kantian qualifications for this application of 'categories' to
   the economic structure of society.
   Keywords: Categories of Understanding, Continuity, Convexity, Psyche,
   Revealed Preferences, Synthetic a priori
   JEL: B4 B49 D0 D01 D9
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=B4%20B49%20D0%20D01%20D9>
   Date: 2022–06–15
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:113677&r=
   6. From Addition to Multiplication: The Labour Theory Of Value and the
   Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Part One: Profit and Surplus-Value in
   light of Transaction Costs
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/RePEc:usi:wpaper:884>
   By: Alberto Battistini
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?aus=Alberto%20Battistini>
   Abstract: this three-parts study presents an institutional and
   evolutionary -or a qualitative and intersubjective-re-interpretation of
   Marx’s version of the labour theory of value. More specifically, in this
   Part One Marx’s own contribution to that theory - that is, the theory of
   surplusvalue, or the difference between use-value and exchange-value of
   labour power as a determinant of profit in perfectly competitive conditions
   and of the contradictory nature of the capital accumulation process- is
   re-dis-covered. Accordingly, the amount that would have been the cost of
   obtaining the same commodity in the noncapitalist Commodity ? Money ?
   Commodity circuit -that is, in the market of independent or smalland
   medium-size producers, takes the place of the direct and indirect quantity
   of working hours contained in a given commodity, thus representing its
   exchange value. By applying - as Marx did- the same pricing rule which
   holds for the other commodities to labour power, therefore, the quantity of
   labour socially necessary to produce subsistence goods is in its turn
   substituted with the amount that is possible to earn from independent
   participation in the production process, without specific means of
   production in the usual meaning of the term. Since the step in terms of
   surplus-labour is then skipped for theoretical as well as practical
   reasons, the use-value of labour-power corresponds to the exchange-value of
   the commodities. Consequently, as in Marx, also in this case a kind of
   profit that derives from the difference between the use-value and the
   exchange-value of labour-power, but measured in terms of transaction costs,
   comes to light. Moreover, because it derives from the aforementioned
   difference, this kind of profit is not eliminated by competition. As a
   consequence, it should be named as ‘Marxian’ or ‘industrial’ profit in
   order to distinguish it from monopoly profit, which instead derives from
   price setting. On the basis of this result, in the next two Parts of the
   study the hypothesis that the principle of the maximization of this kind of
   profit might work as a general positive principle for the economic domain,
   including as special cases Pareto-efficiency and conflict, will be verified
   Keywords: transaction costs; wealth effects; use-value; exchange-value;
   team production; methodological individualism
   JEL: A10 B00 C70 P10 D02
   <http://econpapers.repec.org/scripts/search.pf?jel=A10%20B00%20C70%20P10%20D02>
   Date: 2022–07
   URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:usi:wpaper:884&r=

------------------------------
This nep-hpe issue is ©2022 by  <http://econpapers.repec.org/RAS/pth72.htm>Erik
Thomson. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It
may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If
distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org.
For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese
<http://novarese.org/> at <[log in to unmask]>. Put “NEP” in the
subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by
the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.


ATOM RSS1 RSS2